ESSAYS ON LOCAL BANKING MARKETS
     AND THE CAPITAL CRUNCH
   DURING THE GREAT RECESSION




                          BY

                   DAVID P. GLANCY

              B.A., CLARK UNIVERSITY, 2010

             M.A., BROWN UNIVERSITY, 2011




A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE
REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY
 IN THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AT BROWN UNIVERSITY




              PROVIDENCE, RHODE ISLAND
                      MAY 2016

c Copyright 2016 by David P. Glancy
       This dissertation by David P. Glancy is accepted in its present form

                by the Department of Economics as satisfying the

        dissertation requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.




Date
                                 Doctor David Weil, Adviser




                     Recommended to the Graduate Council




Date
                               Doctor Gauti Eggertsson, Reader




Date
                                   Doctor Neil Mehrotra, Reader




                       Approved by the Graduate Council




Date
                               Pete M. Weber, Dean of the Graduate School




                                        iii
VITA




David Glancy was born July 26th, 1988 in San Francisco, California and attended Towson High
School. He studied at Clark University, graduating summa cum laude with highest honors in Eco-
nomics in 2010. While at Brown University, he was a graduate fellow in the research department of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston and with Spatial Structures in the Social Sciences (S4). He was
the recipient of the Abramson Award for the best third year paper, the S4 Graduate Paper Prize,
and a Graduate Merit Dissertation Fellowship.




                                                iv
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS




I first would like to thank David Weil for providing constant feedback and support regardless of how
far my research drifted from his. Without his patience, I would not have been able to pursue the
topics that excited me in graduate school. Gauti Eggertsson, Neil Mehrotra and Nate Baum-Snow
additionally provided invaluable feedback. Every conversation with them greatly improved the qual-
ity of my work. I’m also grateful to Ross Levine for sparking my initial interest in empirical banking
research.

I’d also like to thank the research department at the Boston Federal Reserve Bank for hosting me
for the last two years. The weekly lunch conversations with Victoria Ivashina, Ali Ozdagli, Joe Peek
and Christina Wang have been enlightening and entertaining. These encounters have left me with
a greater understanding and appreciation of the intricacies regarding the workings of the financial
system than I had before.

My friends in the department, Mari´a Jos´e Boccardi Chalela, Greg Casey, Morgan Hardy, Michelle
Marcus, Ang´elica Meinhofer Santiago, Sanjay Singh and Tim Squires, deftly alternated between sup-
porting me in and distracting me from my academic pursuits, depending on whatever was necessary
at the time. Nick Coleman guided me through the ins-and-outs of both banking research and the job
search process. Finally, Aaron Crootof, Anders Ohman, Ximena Ojopi and Brittany Mayweather
took on the Sisyphean task of keeping me sane throughout graduate school, for which I am eternally
grateful.




                                                  v
PREFACE



There is a vast literature studying the interactions between bank lending and the local economy.
Whether it was bank failures during the savings-and-loan crisis reducing local income (Ashcraft,
2005), the lending contraction from Japanese banks during the early 90s reducing US construction
activity (Peek and Rosengren, 2000), or bank branch deregulation between 1976 and 1994 increasing
growth (Jayaratne and Strahan, 1996), there is substantial evidence that the performance of local
banks and the local economy are tightly entwined.

However, since those periods, there has been a drastic shift in American credit markets which has
the potential to decouple the health of local banks from the strength of the local economy. The
removal of interstate branching restrictions in 1994 has created a banking system increasingly dom-
inated by large geographically dispersed banks who are less subject to shocks from any given area
(Morgan et al., 2004). Additionally, improvements in information and communication technology
have reduced the importance of proximity in the provision of small business credit, enabling distant
firms to increasingly compete with local ones (Petersen and Rajan, 2002). Finally, the continued
rise of securitization has separated the act loan origination from loan funding, allowing credit risk
to increasingly be held by dispersed investors instead of local banks (Loutskina and Strahan, 2009).

In this dissertation, I demonstrate that despite these changes in the banking system, the linkages
between the health of local banks and the local economy remain strong. Moreover, these linkages
played a fundamental role in propagating local real estate shocks to the general economy during the
Great Recession. Chapter 1 demonstrates that banks locating in weak real estate markets experi-
enced increases in non-performing loans and declines in equity, ultimately resulting in a contraction
in the supply of credit to local businesses. Chapter 2 extends this work to show that this credit
contraction had large employment effects during the Great Recession. Counties whose banks were
exposed to real estate declines elsewhere along their branch network experienced contractions in
small business lending and employment, especially in young firms, firms in financially dependent
industries, and firms close to adversely affected banks. Chapter 3 justifies the emphasis on local
banking markets, showing that bank mark-ups respond to the availability of competitors within 5
miles of their branches instead of the more conventionally used MSA level market definition.

The first two chapters are motivated by the observation that markets in the United States which
experienced large declines in house prices, were plagued by bank failures, contractions in lending
and falling employment during the Great Recession. These early chapters ask whether these declines
in lending and employment were caused by the bank distress, or whether the ultimate cause of this
regional turmoil laid outside the banking section.

Chapter 1 starts by studying how falling house prices impacted the supply of credit. I use a difference-
in-differences approach to test whether commercial lending fell due to low demand, or whether banks
were contracting supply. I exploit variation in banks’ lending portfolios or funding structure which
determine how sensitive a bank’s lending capacity is to house price shocks. First, an increase in loans
losses and a decline in equity should only impact a bank close to their capital constraint. Second,
banks which held more construction loans would take larger losses when house prices fell, and thus
should reduce commercial lending more than other banks facing the same declines. I show that only
highly leveraged banks or construction oriented banks contract commercial lending, indicating that
falling house prices predominantly impacted the supply of bank credit.


                                                   vi
                                                                                                   vii

Chapter 2 also addresses the question of how falling house prices impacted bank lending, however it
uses geographic variation in bank locations to separate supply from demand. I use bank-by-county
small business lending data from the Community Reinvestment Act to estimate lending growth as a
function of a bank’s multimarket exposure to real estate shocks and county fixed effects. I demon-
strate that bank’s don’t actually reallocate credit away from counties with falling house prices.
Instead, exposed banks cut lending uniformly throughout their network. The county fixed effects
have no impact on the relationship between bank exposure and lending growth, indicating that
lending fell because exposed banks contracted credit everywhere, not because there was low demand
in areas with falling house prices.

More importantly, this chapter shows that this contraction in bank lending impacted local employ-
ment. The exposure of local banks to falling house prices in other counties, MSAs, and geographically
distant counties caused employment to fall within the county from 2007 to 2010. This even holds
controlling for the local decline in house prices. Consistent with a contraction in the supply of bank
lending driving the employment declines, employment fell the most in young firms, firms in finan-
cially dependent industries and in firms close to exposed banks. Overall, I find that bank lending
contractions due to falling house prices explain over half of the relationship between housing wealth
shocks and employment declines and 39% of the decline in employment during the great recession.

Chapter 3 deviates from the topic of the financial crisis and instead justifies the emphasis on local
banking markets in the previous chapters. Motivated by earlier research showing that individuals
and small businesses primarily rely on banks with nearby branches, I construct measures of deposit
concentration in the area directly surrounding a bank’s branches. Although US bank merger policy,
as well as the bulk of academic work on bank market power, emphasize concentration at the MSA
level, I show that this traditional measure of concentration ceases to predict bank mark-ups or
profitability once the more local concentration is accounted for. I show that bank lending rates
depend most strongly on the availability of competitors within 5 miles of their branches, indicating
a limited ability to substitute towards distant banks. This lack of competition also matters for
labor market outcomes. Firms in locally concentrated markets expand less in response to exogenous
demand shocks, indicating the existence of greater financial constraints. This is particularly true of
young firms, who would be the most dependent on banks for external finance.
Contents

1 House Price Declines and the Supply of Bank Credit                                                                                  1
  1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    1
      1.1.1 Previous Literature . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    4
  1.2 Empirical Strategy and Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    5
      1.2.1 Empirical Strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .       .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    5
      1.2.2 Conceptual Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .           .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    6
      1.2.3 Relation to Empirical Specification . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    8
      1.2.4 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .     .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   11
  1.3 Findings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   12
      1.3.1 Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .       .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   12
      1.3.2 Main Findings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   14
  1.4 Extensions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   16
      1.4.1 Commercial Loan Utilization . . . . . . . . . . . .          .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   16
      1.4.2 Are Results Driven by Loan Losses? . . . . . . . .           .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   17
      1.4.3 Effects on Other Lending . . . . . . . . . . . . . .         .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   18
      1.4.4 How Much of the Decline is Due to Supply Shocks              .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   20
  1.5 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .     .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   22
  1.6 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .     .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   24
      1.6.1 Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   24
      1.6.2 Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .     .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   25

2 Housing Bust, Bank Lending & Employment: Evidence From Multimarket Banks                                                           38
  2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                 38
      2.1.1 Relation to Previous Literature . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                      41
  2.2 Data Sources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                   44
      2.2.1 Real Estate Shock Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                      44
      2.2.2 Lending Growth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                       45
      2.2.3 Labor Market Outcomes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                        46
  2.3 Empirical Strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                   47
      2.3.1 Impact of Real Estate Exposure on Small Business Lending . . . . . . . . . .                                             47
      2.3.2 Impact of Real Estate Exposure on Employment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                             48
  2.4 Findings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                 52
      2.4.1 Exposed Banks Cut Small Business Lending . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                           52
      2.4.2 Bank Exposure Causes Employment Declines . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                             53
  2.5 Robustness and Extensions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                      57
      2.5.1 Wage Adjustment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                        57
      2.5.2 Instrumenting with Earlier Branch Locations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                          58
      2.5.3 Alternative Bank Health Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                         59
      2.5.4 Alternative Controls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                     59
  2.6 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                   60
  2.7 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                   62
      2.7.1 Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                    62


                                                   i
CONTENTS                                                                                                                                   vi

         2.7.2   Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                   66
         2.7.3   Theory Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                      76

3 A Spatial Measure of Banking Competition                                                                                                 83
  3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .    .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    83
  3.2 Background and Motivation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .         .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    87
      3.2.1 Bank Concentration and Competition . . . . .              .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    87
      3.2.2 Importance of Proximity in Banking . . . . . .            .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    88
      3.2.3 Implications for Bank Market Definition . . . .           .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    89
  3.3 Local Concentration Measure . . . . . . . . . . . . . .         .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    90
      3.3.1 Index Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    90
      3.3.2 How Do Local and MSA Concentration Differ?                .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    91
  3.4 Local Market Structure and Bank Performance . . . .             .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    92
      3.4.1 Data & Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .          .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    92
      3.4.2 Effects of 6km Local Concentration . . . . . . .          .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    94
      3.4.3 Effects by Distance Parameter . . . . . . . . .           .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    96
  3.5 Local Concentration and Young Firm Finance . . . . .            .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    98
      3.5.1 Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    98
      3.5.2 Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .         .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    99
      3.5.3 Data and Specification . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   100
      3.5.4 Findings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   101
  3.6 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   102
  3.7 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   104
      3.7.1 Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .       .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   104
      3.7.2 Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   111
      3.7.3 Decomposition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .         .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   116
      3.7.4 Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   117
      3.7.5 Data Sources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   120
List of Tables

 1.1    Summary Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                 .   .   .   25
 1.2    Housing Declines and Loan Non-performance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                        .   .   .   26
 1.3    Housing Declines and Loan Growth: By Loan Type . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                         .   .   .   27
 1.4    Housing Declines and Commercial Lending Growth: By Leverage . . . . . . . .                                            .   .   .   28
 1.5    Housing Declines and Commercial Lending Growth: By Construction Exposure                                               .   .   .   29
 1.6    Housing Declines and Commercial Loan Utilization: By Leverage . . . . . . . .                                          .   .   .   30
 1.7    Housing Declines and Commercial Loan Utilization: By Construction Exposure                                             .   .   .   31
 1.8    Are Results Driven By Real Estate Losses: Leverage Specifications . . . . . . .                                        .   .   .   32
 1.9    Are Results Driven By Real Estate Losses: Construction Specifications . . . . .                                        .   .   .   33
 1.10   Housing Declines and Total Lending: By Leverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                        .   .   .   34
 1.11   Housing Declines and Real Estate Lending: By Leverage . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                        .   .   .   35
 1.12   Housing Declines and Construction Lending: By Leverage . . . . . . . . . . . .                                         .   .   .   36
 1.13   Housing Declines and CRE Lending: By Leverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                          .   .   .   37

 2.1    Summary Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   66
 2.2    Growth in Number of Small Loans . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   67
 2.3    Employment Growth: By Tradability . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   68
 2.4    Employment Growth: IV with Out of Market Shocks            .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   69
 2.5    Employment Growth: By Financial Dependence . .             .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   70
 2.6    Employment Growth: By Age . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   71
 2.7    Tract Employment Growth . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   72
 2.8    Evidence of Wage Adjustment . . . . . . . . . . . . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   73
 2.9    County Growth: Health of 2002 Branches . . . . . .         .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   74
 2.10   Tract Growth: Health of 2002 Branches . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   75

 3.1    Impact of Concentration on Loan Rates . . . . . . . . . .              .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   111
 3.2    Impact of Concentration on Deposit Rates . . . . . . . . .             .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   112
 3.3    Impact of Concentration on Bank Profits . . . . . . . . .              .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   113
 3.4    Concentration and Response to Demand Shocks . . . . . .                .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   114
 3.5    Concentration and Response to Demand Shocks: By Age                    .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   115




                                                  vii
List of Figures

 1.1   Lending Elasticities: By Bank Leverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                                        24

 2.1   Distribution of Lender Distances . . . . . . . . . . . .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    62
 2.2   Effect of Bank Health: Distance Based Instruments . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    63
 2.3   Effects of Bank Health on Tract Growth: By Distance        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    64
 2.4   Joint Confidence Regions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .    65

 3.1   Declining Probability of Lending Over Distance . . . . .       .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   104
 3.2   Hypothetical Bank Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   105
 3.3   How Similar Are MSA and Local Concentration? . . . .           .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   106
 3.4   Different Trends in Concentration . . . . . . . . . . . . .    .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   107
 3.5   Impact of Concentration on Loan Rates . . . . . . . . .        .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   108
 3.6   Impact of Concentration on Commercial Loan Rates . .           .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   109
 3.7   Financial Constraints and Response to Demand Shocks            .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   .   110




                                                viii
Chapter 1

House Price Declines and the
Supply of Bank Credit

“Making credit accessible to sound small                      “It’s absurd to argue we need more

businesses is crucial to our economic re-                    bank lending when demand is collapsing

covery and so should be front and center                     throughout the economy”

among our current policy challenges”

                         -Ben Bernanke                                       -Atif Mian & Amir Sufi

1.1     Introduction

How did falling house prices impact bank lending during the Great Recession? Banks in weak

real estate markets experienced a significant deterioration in loan performance and originated fewer

commercial loans, however the degree to which this decline in lending reflected a contraction in the

supply of credit remains controversial. Given the severity of the employment losses in areas with

falling house prices, identifying the mechanism by which falling house prices impacted bank lending

is a crucial component of understanding the recession.

   This chapter presents evidence that falling house prices resulted in a contraction in the supply

of bank credit. The hypothesis is that banks which located in areas where house prices fell took

losses on their loan portfolio, thus harming their capital positions. Since asymmetric information

problems can make issuing new equity prohibitively costly (Myers and Majluf, 1984), banks were

forced to reduce lending in order to deleverage. Consequently, this capital crunch channel can explain

the contraction in lending in areas where house prices fell. Furthermore, as credit supply shocks

have been shown to impact labor markets (Ashcraft, 2005; Benmelech et al., 2011; Chodorow-Reich,

2014), this channel may also have contributed to the employment losses in these areas.



                                                  1
    However, the relationship between falling house prices and lending growth could also be plau-

sibly attributed to a reduction in the demand for loans. For example, falling house prices could

reduce aggregate demand (Mian and Sufi, 2014) or the value of firm collateral (Fort et al., 2013;

Mehrotra and Sergeyev, 2014). If these effects reduced either the incentive of firms to borrow or the

creditworthiness of local firms, then lending would have fallen regardless of what happened to bank

capital. Under this demand channel, the contraction in lending is due to a dearth of viable lending

opportunities instead of adverse shocks to the health of local banks.

    To disentangle supply from demand, I exploit cross sectional variation in the composition of bank

balance sheets to identify banks whose ability to support new lending were more vulnerable to real

estate shocks. General economic turmoil reducing the demand for loans would broadly affect the

commercial lending of local banks. However, the capital crunch hypothesis predicts that some banks

in particular would contract lending much more than others when local house prices fall. First,

only banks close to their capital constraint should cut lending in response to a contraction in house

prices. Banks with an adequate capital buffer could have their equity decline, but would have no

need to shrink their assets in order to remain above regulatory capital ratios. Second, banks which

devoted more of their portfolio to construction loans would experience larger losses.1 Since these

banks would experience a greater shock to equity, they should contract lending the most.

    Specifically, I use a difference-in-differences approach to test how house price declines impact the

growth in commercial and industrial (C&I) lending in (1) banks which are highly leveraged versus

banks which are further their capital constraint, and (2) banks which are highly exposed to the

construction sector versus banks which aren’t. Thus I can use banks which face similar house price

declines, or operate in the same market, as a control for local demand. This allows me to assess how

real estate shocks impact the supply of credit.

    I consistently find that it was the treated banks (banks with a high construction exposure or

high leverage) who cut lending where house prices fell. Consider the effects of the national 15%

decline in house prices between the beginning of 2007 and 2010. Untreated banks are predicted to

have only minimally responded to this shock, with low leverage banks cutting commercial lending

by 1.2% and low construction banks cutting lending by 0.1% between the start of 2008 and end of

2010. Treated banks are another story; this decline is predicted to have caused a 5.0% decline in

commercial lending in leveraged banks and a 6.1% decline in construction oriented banks over those

three years. Essentially the only banks which reduced lending in response to falling house prices
   1 Cole and White (2012); Friend et al. (2013) note that it was predominantly banks whose portfolios were concen-

trated in construction lending who failed during the Great Recession. I also show that falling house prices resulted in
an increase in non-performing construction loans that dwarfed the effects on loan performance in other categories.


                                                          2
were the banks whose ability to lend would be sensitive to real estate declines. This suggests the

contraction in lending was essentially due to a contraction in the supply of credit.

   This finding is robust to numerous alternative specifications. Whether the treatment variables

are binary or continuous, whether I control for demand using local house price growth or CBSA-

quarter fixed effects, whether or not I weight by the size of the bank’s commercial lending portfolio,

and whether or not I include additional controls, makes little difference for the primary findings. I

consistently find that treated banks exhibit a significantly greater sensitivity to house price declines

than untreated banks.

   Next, I take two approaches to provide auxiliary evidence in favor of my proposed channel. First,

one may be concerned that my treatment variables are related to changes in demand. For example,

the decision to operate with little capital may reflect high loan demand during the boom, which

reverted during the bust. To assuage this concern, I study the impact that the treatment variables

have on commercial loan utilization. If treated banks face lower loan demand in areas with falling

house prices, then their customers would be less likely to draw down on their lines of credit, resulting

in a decline in utilization. However, I find little difference in loan utilization in treated and untreated

banks. If anything treated banks have utilization increase when house prices fall, indicating that

they don’t experience differentially low demand.

   Second, I show that the findings are explained by poorer loan performance in distressed real estate

markets. Banks with more non-performing loans cut lending, especially if they are highly leveraged.

Once the non-performing loan rate and its interaction with bank leverage are included, the primary

explanatory variables cease to predict lending growth. If leveraged banks or construction oriented

banks cut lending even if their loans continued to pay off, this could indicate that they made loans

to firms whose demand was more sensitive to house price declines. That loan losses take precedence

over falling house prices in predicting lending increases confidence that it is indeed a capital crunch

driven by non-performing loans which precipitated the decline in lending.

   Lastly, I extend the analysis to other types of loans. Since the C&I lending category excludes loans

backed by real estate, it may be unsurprising that the contraction reflected a decline in the ability

of banks to lend. However, lending backed by real estate is more likely to fall due to declines in the

value of collateral backing lending or the lack of profitable construction related investments. I find

that national 15% decline in house prices resulted in a 2.4% decline in total lending for unleveraged

banks versus a 5.8% decline for leveraged banks over the course of 2008 to 2010. These effects are

2.5% and 6.3% for lending backed by real estate, 10% and 13.8% for construction lending, and 1.2%



                                                    3
versus 3.8% for loans backed by non-farm non-residential properties.2 Although construction lending

seems to have fallen mostly due to low demand, in other categories the decline in house prices had a

dramatically larger effect on lending in leveraged banks. Across the board, leveraged banks reduce

lending in response to this 15% shock by about 3 or 4 percentage points more than unleveraged

banks.

    The ramifications of this capital crunch are thus potentially wide reaching. Previous research

has demonstrated that the availability of commercial credit impacts employment and investment

(Almeida et al., 2012; Campello et al., 2010; Chodorow-Reich, 2014), construction and CRE lending

impacts unemployment and construction activity (Peek and Rosengren, 2000; Benmelech et al.,

2011) and mortgage credit impacts employment and output growth (Mondragon, 2014; Loutskina

and Strahan, 2015). The broad decline in the availability of credit across these various lending

categories has the potential to explain much of the observed economic turmoil in distressed real

estate markets during this period. How these bank real estate losses impacted local employment

will be the subject of the second chapter of this dissertation.


1.1.1      Previous Literature

This paper fits cleanly into two literatures. First, there is an old literature demonstrating that

declines in bank capital impact the lending of capital constrained banks. This was widely studied

in the context of the recession in the early 1990s, with a particular emphasis on the New England

banks who were reeling from the bursting of a house price and construction bubble in the late

1980s (Bernanke et al., 1991; Hancock and Wilcox, 1994; Peek and Rosengren, 1994, 1995). Further

evidence in support of the importance of these capital shocks were also presented in the context of

the Japanese banking crisis following the collapse of Japanese land prices in the early 1990s (Peek

and Rosengren, 1997, 2000; Gan, 2007).

    Peek and Rosengren (1995) and Gan (2007) are the closest to this paper methodologically. Peek

and Rosengren (1995) shows that deposits fell in poorly capitalized banks with respect to better

capitalized banks during a period of high bank distress in New England. Gan (2007) shows that

firms borrowing from banks whose assets were highly oriented in real estate loans received less

credit following the sharp contraction in Japanese land values. Similar to these papers, I exploit

cross sectional variation in bank leverage or construction exposure to determine how these real estate

shocks impacted the supply of bank lending. I differ by additionally using regional variation in the
   2 For construction and non-farm non-residential lending I report estimates from the weighted specifications because

there are many banks who engage in a minimal amount of these types of lending. The differences are starker in the
unweighted specifications.


                                                          4
degree of real estate distress, whereas the other papers focused on one area experiencing a negative

shock.

   The second strand of literature studies the determinants of bank lending during the Great Re-

cession. Previous work has demonstrated that lending fell for numerous different reasons, including

stresses on bank liquidity (Ivashina and Scharfstein, 2010; Cornett et al., 2011), mortgage backed

security exposure (Santos, 2011), and losses in banks exposed to GSE preferred stocks (Rice and

Rose, 2014).

   The most relevant papers to me are Huang and Stephens (2011); Berrospide et al. (2013); Bord

et al. (2014), who show that the multimarket exposure of banks to real estate shocks creates within

county or MSA variation in lending. Namely banks with a greater exposure to real estate declines in

other areas reduce lending relative to less exposed banks, indicating that falling house prices result

in a contraction in the supply of lending. My difference-in-differences approach compliments these

papers as it allows me to study the effects of falling house prices on predominantly single market

banks. As these single market banks account for vast the majority of the banks in the US (6991 out

of 7571), this is important in itself. Additionally, there is little geographically disaggregated lending

data available. Thus by using a methodology only requiring aggregate balance sheet data, I can

increase the scope of the work in terms of the outcome variables I analyze, in addition to expanding

the sample.

   The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows: The next section describes the data and empirical

strategy. Section 3 presents the main findings. Section 4 provides additional evidence for the channel,

and extends the methodology to other lending categories. Section 5 concludes.



1.2      Empirical Strategy and Data

1.2.1    Empirical Strategy

The primary analysis is based on the following specifications:


              yb,m,q = β1 ∆ln(House P ricem,q ) × T reatb,m,q−1 + β2 ∆ln(House P ricem,q )
                                                                                                    (1.1)
                                                                + γXb,m,q−1 + δq + b,m,q


           yb,m,q = β1 ∆ln(House P ricem,q ) × T reatb,m,q−1 + γXb,m,q−1 + δm,q + b,m,q            (1.2)




                                                   5
In the main part of the paper, yb,m,q is the quarterly growth in commercial and industrial lending for

a bank b locating in market m. The market is taken to be the CBSA or rural county, henceforth just

referred to as a CBSA for brevity.3 ∆ln(House P ricem,q ) is the house price growth over the last

year in m, T reatb,m,q−1 is a bank balance sheet variable which influences how sensitive the bank’s

lending capacity is to real estate shocks, δq and δm,q are quarter and CBSA-quarter fixed effects

respectively, and Xb,m,q−1 a set of bank controls including T reatb,m,q−1 .4 The sample period covers

2007 through 2010, and includes banks which held over 50% of their deposits in a single CBSA in

2006. Standard errors are clustered by CBSA.

    T reatb,m,q−1 is a measure of either the bank’s exposure to the construction sector or leverage.

I use one of four variables: the ratio of a bank’s tangible assets to tangible equity (Leverage), an

indicator for whether this variable is above the median for the CBSA-quarter (High Leverage),
                                                  .
construction lending to bank equity (Construction Equity), and indicator for whether this ratio is
                                                            .
above the median for the CBSA-quarter (High Construction Equity).

    Many lenders are almost entirely specialized in real estate lending, creating a risk of overly em-

phasizing large percentage swings in C&I lending which actually have an inconsequential influence

on aggregate lending. Thus in addition to OLS specifications, I also weight by the value of out-

standing commercial loans at the end of the previous quarter. In the weighted specifications, I drop

observations more than five standard deviations above the mean in commercial lending.5


1.2.2        Conceptual Framework

In order to interpret the coefficients in this specification, consider the following simple model of banks

engaging in monopolistic competition. A bank in market m lends to a set of borrowers indexed by

i ∈ Im . Total borrowing for every i is a CES composite of borrowing from local banks, generating

a standard iso-elastic demand for each bank b from borrower i.6

                                                                    rib −
                                                  Lbi = ξib Li (       )
                                                                    ri
   3A  CBSA contains an urban center of at least 10,000 people and adjacent areas with strong commuting ties.
   4 Other  control variables include: ln(assets), non-core deposit percent, mortgage back security holdings to assets,
and share of lending in the commercial and industrial loan category.
   5 There are some large lenders that only locate in one market because they don’t rely on local branches for lending.

Including them in the weighted specification would skew the findings substantially, as the estimated coefficients would
largely reflect the lending growth in a few banks which aren’t actually predominantly engaging in local lending.
                                                                                                              ! 
                                                                                                               −1
                                                                                                        −1
   6 The amount borrowed from each b, Lb , is done so as to minimize                          b) 1
                                                                        R b b
                                                                                                  (Lb )  db
                                                                                        R
                                           i                              r  L
                                                                            i i db s.t.    (ξi       i             = Li .
                                                                             Ωm               Ωm
                                                                                  1
                                                                  ξib (rib )1− db) 1− , gives the above demand curve.
                                                          R
Solving this minimization problem, and denoting ri = (
                                                         Ωm




                                                              6
Where rib is the interest rate charged by bank b to borrower i, ri is the overall cost of bank borrowing

for i,  is the elasticity of demand, and ξib is a demand shifter integrating to 1.

   Given a certain level of aggregate lending Lb , the bank will allocate credit across borrowers in

order to maximize profit subject to demand curves and the adding up constraint.

                                                   X
                                 maximize                Lbi rib
                                    {rib }
                                                  i∈Im
                                                   X                                        rib −
                                 subject to              Lbi = Lb , {Lbi = ξib Li (            ) } ∀i
                                                                                            ri
                                                  i∈Im


   This results in a constant optimal lending rate for bank b:

                                                                    Db 1
                                                         rb = (        )  ∀i                                      (1.3)
                                                                    Lb

where Db =               ξib Li ri measures the level of demand for loans from b.
                  P
                  i∈Im
   Next, assume that the marginal cost of lending for a bank is an increasing function c() of its
           Lb
leverage   Eb
              ,   where E b is the bank’s equity. Using the previous expression and equating the marginal

revenue from lending with the marginal cost, we get the following inverse supply curve:

                                                                     Lb
                                                        rb =        c( b )                                         (1.4)
                                                                 −1 E

Combining the demand equation in (3) with the supply equation in (4) and log-linearizing produces

the following equations governing the growth in lending and interest rates:


                                                  ˆ b = ηb E
                                                  L        ˆ b + (1 − η b )D
                                                                           ˆb                                      (1.5)

                                                               ηb ˆ b ˆb)
                                                     rˆb =       (D − E                                            (1.6)
                                                               

Thus lending growth is a weighted average of demand growth and equity growth, with a weight
                                                     b
                                              b    ( L b ) −1 −1
on equity growth: η b = (1 + (c0 ( E
                                    L
                                      b)
                                                     E
                                                       b )   ) .            This means that equity shocks matter more if
                                                  c( L b )
                                                    E

borrowers are more able to substitute between banks ( is high) or if there is a greater elasticity of
                                                                        b
                                                             b     ( Lb )
marginal cost with respect to leverage: ( c0 ( E
                                               L
                                                 b)
                                                                     E
                                                                       b        is high).
                                                                   c( L b   )
                                                                      E

   Since this paper focuses on C&I lending instead of total lending, consider the subset of commercial

borrowers Im,CI ⊂ Im . Then the total C&I lending for b is LbCI = (rb )−            ξib Li ri . Thus the
                                                                                P
                                                                                                        i∈Im,CI




                                                                    7
growth in C&I lending is
                                           ˆ b = −ˆ
                                           L            ˆb
                                                   rb + D
                                             CI          CI
                                                                                                         (1.7)
                                                        ˆb − E
                                                = −η b (D    ˆb) + D
                                                                   ˆb
                                                                     CI

           b
                                 ξib Li ri denotes the level of demand for commercial bank loans for b. Equa-
                         P
    Where DCI ≡
                       i∈Im,CI
tion (7) shows that the growth in C&I lending can be broken into two parts: a component reflecting
                                          ˆ b ) and a component reflecting the cost of borrowing
changes in demand for commercial lending (D CI

               rb ). The object of interest in this paper is the elasticity of lending growth with
from a bank (−ˆ

respect to house price growth:


                                            ˆb
                                           dL          ∂rb   ∂Dˆb
                                              CI                CI
                                                 = −      +
                                           dHˆm       ∂Hˆm     ˆm
                                                              ∂H
                                                   | {z }    | {z }
                                                   Credit Crunch    Demand
                                                      Channel       Channel

    Namely I want to test whether falling house prices reduced the supply of commercial lending
         b                                                                         ˆb
                                                                                  ∂D
( ∂∂r
    Hˆ       < 0) or whether they reduced the demand for commercial loans ( ∂ HˆCI > 0). As I will show
         m                                                                           m

below, how this elasticity varies by leverage or construction exposure will be informative in assessing

the magnitude of the demand and credit crunch channels.


1.2.3          Relation to Empirical Specification

Role of Bank Leverage Bank leverage matters because leveraged banks will face a steeper

marginal cost curve. Banks with excess capital can cheaply increase deposits if they want to expand,

whereas banks on their capital constraint would need to raise new equity, which is costly due to

asymmetric information problems (Myers and Majluf, 1984). Additionally higher leverage increases

bank risk and makes uninsured wholesale funding more expensive. As a consequence, leverage

increases η b , making lending growth more sensitive to equity growth.

    To relate the theory to empirical strategy, suppose that the key variables in (7) take the following

functional forms:

                                              
                                                η b = η0 + ηT Tb
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                                ˆ b = e0 + eH Hˆm
                                              
                                              E
                                              
                                                                                                         (1.8)
                                                ˆ b = d0 + dH H
                                                              ˆm
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                               D
                                              
                                              
                                              
                                                ˆ b = c0 + cH Hˆm
                                              
                                              D
                                              
                                                  CI


    Where Tb is the treatment variable, indicating whether the bank is highly leveraged. These


                                                         8
equations say that falling house prices impact bank equity, overall loan demand and commercial

loan demand the same in leveraged and unleveraged banks. However, shocks to bank equity matter

more for leveraged banks due to the fact that they are closer to their capital constraint (ηT > 0).

   Combining (7) and (8) gives commercial lending growth as a function of bank leverage, house

price growth and their interaction as in the estimating equation in (1):


     L                                                ˆ m + [η0 (eH − dH ) + cH ] H
     ˆ b = [η0 (e0 − d0 ) + c0 ] + [ηT (eH − dH )] Tb H                           ˆ m + [ηT (e0 − d0 )]Tb
                                   |      {z     }          |        {z        }
                                         β1                                    β2


   Thus the coefficient on the interaction term between the leverage indicator and house price

growth should provide us with the term ηT (eH − dH ). This is easier to interpret when put in terms
                                ˆb
                               ∂L         b              ˆb
                                                        ∂L         b
                                   CI ∂r                    CI ∂r
of partial derivatives: β1 =            ˆ m |T =1
                                ∂ rˆb ∂ H
                                                    −            ˆ m |T =0 .
                                                         ∂ rˆb ∂ H
                                                                               Intuitively, β1 shows the difference in

the supply effect between unlevered and levered banks. A positive coefficient means that leveraged

banks cut lending more when house prices fall. Under the assumption that these types of banks

experience the same demand shocks, this differential can be attributed to increases in the cost of

lending for leveraged banks.
                                                                                                ˆb
                                                                                               ∂L         b              ˆb
                                                                                                                        ∂D
                      ˆ m (β2 ) gives us the term η0 (eH − dH ) + cH , which is                    CI ∂r
   The coefficient on H                                                                                 ˆ m |T =0   +     ˆm .
                                                                                                                           CI
                                                                                                ∂ rˆb ∂ H               ∂H

Thus the coefficient on house price growth will give the sum of the demand effect of falling house

prices, and the supply effect for untreated banks. Given that η0 > 0, and the fact that β1 > 0 =⇒
                                                                          ˆ m provides an upper
eH > dH , we know that η0 (eH − dH ) > 0. As a result, the coefficient on H
                                  ˆb
                                 ∂D
bound for the demand effect ( ∂ HˆCI ).
                                     m

   The intuition here is that shocks to equity matter more for leveraged banks. If real estate shocks

impact lending by increasing loan non-performance and decreasing bank equity, this matters more

for banks closer to a regulatory capital ratio. A bank up against a capital constraint would need

to either reduce lending or raise equity to maintain their current leverage after a period of poor

loan performance. A bank further from their constraint could take losses without cutting lending or

raising new equity, since they are permitted to operate at a higher level of leverage.

   Conversely, demand shocks matter less for leveraged banks. Low leverage gives the flexibility to

expand or contract lending as warranted by changes in demand. Banks on their capital constraint

would continue to lend similar amounts after a demand shock because their previous lending was

below what was necessitated by demand due to the capital constraint. Figure 1 demonstrates

graphically that demand shocks impact lending in banks which are not capital constrained, while

loan losses impact lending in banks which are constrained.

   In short, the credit crunch hypothesis predicts that β1 > 0 when Tb,m,q−1 measures bank leverage,

                                                            9
because shocks to equity matter more for banks closer to their capital constraint. The demand

hypothesis predicts falling house prices predominantly impacts loan demand (dH > EH ) meaning

that β1 < 0, because unconstrained banks will cut lending most when demand falls.


Role of Construction Lending Construction exposure matters because it determines how severely

house price declines impact bank equity. When house prices fall in a bank’s market, loan non-

performance and charge-offs increase most drastically for constructions loans. Banks with a high

exposure to construction loans were also disproportionately likely to fail during this period (Cole

and White, 2012; Friend et al., 2013).

   To reflect this, now assume the following functional forms for the variables in equation (7):

                                  
                                   ηb = η
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                    ˆ = e0 + eH H
                                                ˆ m + eT H Tb H
                                                              ˆm
                                  
                                  E
                                  
                                                                                                        (1.9)
                                    ˆ b = d0 + dH H
                                                  ˆ m + dT H Tb H
                                                                ˆm
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                  D
                                  
                                  
                                  
                                    ˆ b = c0 + cH Hˆm
                                  
                                  D
                                  
                                      CI


Thus equity growth is more sensitive to house price shocks in construction oriented banks, as con-

struction and land development loans performed so poorly when house prices fall. Overall demand

for loans is assumed to also to be more sensitive to house price declines, because the profitability

of new construction projects decreases when house prices fall. However, demand for commercial

lending is assumed to be the same across banks facing similar local house price movements, since

commercial lending isn’t real estate backed. Under these assumptions, the equation defining lending

growth is:


     ˆ b = [η(e0 − d0 ) + c0 ] + [η(eT H − dT H )] Tb H
     L                                                ˆ m + [η(eH − dH ) + cH ] H
                                                                                ˆ m + [η(e0 − d0 )]Tb
                                 |      {z       }          |       {z       }
                                       β1                          β2


   The coefficient on the interaction term thus reflects the degree to which a construction heavy

loan portfolio impacts bank equity versus overall loan demand. If falling house prices impact lending

through the credit crunch channel, it should be banks which had previously originated construction

loans who cut lending the most, as losses on these construction loans cause equity to fall. Alter-

natively, if falling house prices predominantly impact loan demand, then this should impact banks

regardless of their previous construction lending. Again, β1 > 0 would be evidence in favor of the

capital crunch channel.


                                                   10
1.2.4     Data

Data on lending, bank equity and non-performing loans come from the Call Reports, a quarterly

filing of bank balance sheet variables. Since bank holding companies are expected to be a source of

strength for distressed subsidiaries (Houston et al., 1997; Ashcraft, 2004), I aggregate the balance

sheet variables of multibank holding companies to the level of the highest holding company. I use

observations from the first quarter of 2007 through the end of 2010.


Dependent Variables              The main dependent variable of interest is the growth in commercial and

industrial lending: ∆ln(C&I Loans)b,m,q . This measures the quarterly growth in the value of loans

outstanding to businesses. This excludes business loans backed by real estate (which are reported

separately). I additionally test how falling house prices impact the growth in bank assets, securities

holdings, equity, as well as various other lending variables. Since these variables sometimes contain

extreme outliers, I drop the highest and lowest 1% of observations of the dependent variable in the

regressions.

   I also demonstrate how locating in a market with falling house prices impacts loan performance.

A loan is considered non-performing if it is 90 days past due or not accruing interest. The non-

performing loan rate for a particular type of loan, e.g. construction loans, is the ratio of the value

of non-performing loans to total lending for the category.

   The final dependent variable of interest is the change in the commercial and industrial loan

utilization rate: ∆C&I U tilizationb,m,q . The preferred measure of the utilization rate would be:

                                           .
     C&I U tilizationb,m,q = C&I Loansb,m,q (C&I Loansb,m,q + U nused C&I Loansb,m,q )


However, unused commitments on commercial and industrial loans is unavailable until 2010, so I fol-

low Kashyap et al. (2002) and use ”other commitments” which predominantly reflects commitments

to make C&I loans instead. This variable reflects changes in the tendency of firms to draw on their

lines of credit. If a certain type of bank experiences a decrease in the demand for loans, this could

show up as a decrease in the utilization of available credit.


Independent Variables     I calculate leverage as the ratio of tangible assets to tangible equity:
                                        .
Leverage = (Assets − Intangible Assets) (Equity − Intangible Assets). Where intangible assets

include variables such as good will or mortgage serving rights.7 My measure of exposure to the
  7 Results   are essentially unchanged using tier 1 leverage or the ratio of assets to capital.




                                                            11
                                   .
construction sector is Construction Equity, where Construction is the value of outstanding con-

struction and land development loans. High Leverage is an indicator variable taking the value of
                                                                             .
1 if Leverage is above the median for the CBSA-quarter. High Construction Equity is defined

analogously. When I use the variables in their continuous form, I winsorize at the 5% level.8

    Finally, house price data comes from the FHFA, who construct a repeat sales index on single

family properties securitized by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac. For banks locating in an MSA, I use

the MSA level index. For banks outside an MSA, I use the index for rural areas within the state.9

I match banks to CBSAs or counties using deposit data from the 2006 Summary of Deposits. The

dependent variable of interest is the growth in house prices over the previous year in the CBSA

where the bank held the majority of their 2006 deposits. I exclude banks (or holding companies)

which didn’t have any individual market containing at least 50% of their deposits.

    Summary statistics are found in Table 1. Focusing on the variables weighted by commercial

lending,10 we see that banks faced an average annual decline in house prices of 2%, with a standard

deviation of 6%. The ratio of construction loans to equity averaged about 1 with a considerable

spread; the interquartile range runs from .34 to 1.48. The leverage ratio averages 11.1 with a

standard deviation of 2.1. The mean quarterly growth rate of commercial lending is virtually 0, but

with a standard deviation of 9%.



1.3       Findings

1.3.1      Background

Before turning to the difference-in-differences approach to distinguish between the capital crunch

and demand channel, I first demonstrate that falling house prices did indeed result in increases in

non-performing loans, and a contraction in the size of bank balance sheets.


Housing Declines and Loan Performance Table 2 estimate the non-performing loan rate for

different types of loans as a function of the house price growth over the last year in the bank’s market

and quarter fixed effects. Banks in regions with falling house prices unsurprising see increases in

non-performing loans. Focusing on panel 1 with the unweighted regressions, a 5% decline in house
   8 This matters little for the construction variable, however it is important for the findings with the leverage variable.

Banks at either extreme of leverage will be either already past their capital constraint, or not needing to worry about
their capital constraint, so it would make sense that incremental changes in leverage at the extremes wouldn’t impact
the sensitivity of loan supply to equity shocks.
   9 Results are mostly unchanged when just using MSAs, although it reduces the sample substantially.
  10 These exclude banks over five standard deviations above the mean as in the regressions.




                                                            12
prices is found to increase the overall non-performing loan rate from by 0.8% relative to a mean of

2.2%. Columns 2 and 3 show that this coefficient largely reflects the effect that falling house prices

has on construction loans. The 5% decline in house prices increases the non-performing loan rate for

non-construction loans by only 0.4%, while it raises the non-performing loan rate for construction

loans by 2.5%. Thus while construction lending accounted for less than 10% of bank lending, it

was a primary culprit for the rise in non-performing loans in banks located in distressed real estate

markets.

    The effects of falling house prices on loan performance in non-construction categories is typi-

cally an order of magnitude smaller than for construction loans. The non-performing loan rate for

commercial loans and loans to individuals rise by 0.2% and 0.1% respectively in response to a 5%

decline in house prices. Even the performance of other real estate loans are much less sensitive to

real estate shocks, with a 5% decline raising the non-performing loan rate by 0.3% for commercial

real estate (CRE) loans and 0.6% for loans backed by multifamily property.11 Every coefficient is

significant at the 1% level, except for loans to individuals which is significant at the 5% level.

    Panel 2 presents regressions of the same specification, but weighting by the value of loans out-

standing in the category to account for the fact that some banks may participate in very little of

some types of lending and may thus have noisier non-performing loan rates. Overall, the insights

from the OLS regressions remain in tact. A 5% decline in house prices raises the non-performing

loan rate on construction loans by 2.2%, compared to 0.4% for non-construction loans. The coeffi-

cient for multifamily lending falls, and the coefficient for loans to individuals becomes insignificant

despite increasing somewhat in value. However, the key take away doesn’t change: banks in areas

with falling house prices saw a deterioration in loan performance which was largely attributable to

construction loans.


Housing Declines and Lending Growth How did falling house prices impact the size and

composition of local bank balance sheets? Table 3 shows that banks in areas with falling house

prices shrink across the board. The 15% decline in house prices experienced in the US between the

start of 2007 and start of 2010 is predicted to have lowered assets by 2.9%, equity by 7.4%, lending

by 4.1% and commercial lending by 3.4%.12 The lending declines are stronger for real estate loans,

mostly due to a large decline in construction lending.

    Findings are mostly comparable in the unweighted (Panel 1) and weighted (Panel 2) specifica-
  11 CRE loans here refer to loans secured by non-farm non-residential property, and don’t include construction and

land development loans as in some definitions.
  12 An average of a 5% per year decline over the course of 12 quarters (2008-2010) would reduce lending by .05×12×β.

Where β is the coefficient on house price growth in Table 3.


                                                         13
tions. I find evidence of securities holdings falling only in the unweighted specification, while I find

evidence of CRE lending falling only in the weighted specification. The effects on equity are smaller

when I weight (4.6% decline after 3 years of 5% annual declines) but the effects on commercial

lending are larger (4.2% decline over 3 years).

   Recall the mechanism in the capital crunch channel: (1) falling house prices cause loans to

perform poorly, (2) loan losses result in declines in equity pushing banks towards their capital

constraint, (3) banks reduce lending in order to decrease their leverage. All of these elements

are present in the data; banks in distressed real estate markets did have poorly performing loans

and declining lending and equity. However, this isn’t sufficient to prove that the capital crunch

channel was operative. If demand fell faster than the capacity for banks to lend, then the decline

in lending wasn’t due to the decline in equity. It is still possible that banks were able to raise new

equity affordably, but declined to do so due the lack of viable lending opportunities. In order to

demonstrate that the real estate losses actually caused the decline in lending, I next turn to the

analysis using variation across banks facing the same house price declines.


1.3.2    Main Findings

Difference-in-Differences By Leverage Table 4 shows that it was predominantly highly lever-

aged banks who cut commercial lending in response to falling house prices. In Column 1 of the first

panel, I estimate quarterly C&I lending growth as a function of the house price growth over the

previous year, an indicator for whether the bank is above the median in leverage for the area, the

interaction of leverage and house price growth and quarter fixed effects. I find that the elasticity of

quarterly lending growth with respect to house price growth is 0.02 for low leverage banks, but 0.08

for highly leveraged banks, with the difference being significant at the 1% level. The 15% decline in

house prices would thus be predicted to have reduced lending by 5.0% in high leverage banks and

only 1.2% in low leverage banks over the course of 2008 to 2010.

   In the second column, I include CBSA-quarter fixed in order to compare lending of banks which

are operating in the same market, instead of just markets with similar house price appreciation.

The difference in the elasticity of lending growth with respect to house price growth between high

leverage and low leverage banks increases modestly (from 0.0632 to 0.0652) but is almost the same

as before. The extra bank controls in the third column change nothing.

   One might be concerned that many predominantly single market banks have a very small com-

mercial loan portfolio, making the average growth in commercial lending potentially not reflective



                                                  14
of actual changes in credit availability. Columns 4-6 account for differences in the importance of

banks in commercial lending by weighting by the value of the bank’s commercial loan portfolio at

the end of the previous quarter. Here the findings are qualitatively similar and still significant, albeit

somewhat less stark. The lending elasticity is 0.04 for low leverage banks, and statistically different

from zero unlike in the previous specification. For leveraged banks, the elasticity is again 0.08 and

statistically different from the elasticity for unleveraged banks.

   In the bottom panel, I use leverage in its continuous form instead of an indicator and get similar

results. A bank at the 25th percentile in the leverage distribution (8.65) would have an elasticity

of 0.0, namely they don’t reduce commercial lending when house prices fall. A bank at the 75th

percentile (12.05) however has an elasticity of 0.09, comparable to the high leverage group in the

previous specification. The inclusion of the CBSA-quarter fixed effects diminishes the effect some-

what, with the movement along the interquartile range of leverage now increasing the elasticity by

0.07 instead of 0.09. The difference is still significant at the 1% level, and is unchanged by the

inclusion of the bank controls.

   The findings with the continuous form of leverage are weaker in the weighted regressions, but more

consistent in magnitude. Regardless of controls or fixed effects, movement along the interquartile

range of leverage now increases the elasticity of lending with respect to housing price growth by 0.04,

although it is insignificant in the specification with CBSA-quarter fixed effects and bank controls.


Difference-in-Differences By Construction Table 5 repeats the same analysis, except using

exposure to the construction sector instead of leverage. Here we see that the decline in commercial

lending in areas experiencing negative real estate shocks was entirely due to contractions in banks

holding a high value of construction loans. In Column 1 of panel 1, I find that the elasticity of lending

growth with respect to house price growth is 0.00 for banks below the median in construction lending

to equity, but 0.10 for banks highly exposed to the construction sector, with the difference significant

at the 1% level. The 15% national decline in US house prices would thus be predicted to reduce

lending by 6.1% in construction oriented banks but only 0.1% in other banks over the course of 2008

to 2010.

   The inclusion of CBSA-quarter fixed effects and bank controls in Columns 2 & 3 only strengthens

the findings, raising the difference in elasticities from 0.10 to 0.11. Weighting by the size of the

commercial loan portfolio also strengthens the findings slightly, producing differences in elasticities

between 0.10 and 0.12.

   Turning to the specifications using the ratio of construction lending to equity in its continuous


                                                   15
form in the bottom panel, we reach a similar conclusion. A bank at the 25th percentile in the

distribution (0.12) is found to increase quarterly commercial lending by 0.046% in response to a 1%

decline in house prices.13 A bank at the 75th percentile of the distribution (1.02) has an elasticity

which is 0.07 higher than at the 25th percentile. The inclusion of the CBSA-quarter fixed strengthens

the finding marginally, with the interaction between house price growth and construction exposure

remaining consistent throughout.

    Weighting by commercial lending in Columns 4-6 results in slightly smaller differences in elastic-

ities across different values of construction exposure. Moving from the 25th to the 75th percentile

in construction exposure raises the lending elasticity from 0.012 to 0.053. However, the qualitative

result is consistent throughout: bank’s with minimal exposure to construction loans mostly didn’t

cut lending in response to falling house prices. The bulk of the contraction in commercial lending

in weak real estate markets occurred in banks who had initially been originating construction loans,

and hence were taking large losses on their loan portfolio.



1.4         Extensions

1.4.1         Commercial Loan Utilization

Showing that leveraged and construction oriented banks respond more to housing declines can only

be taken to be indicative of a supply shock if these banks aren’t subject to different demand shocks.14

As one cannot directly observe loan demand, I test for a differential effect on a proxy for loan demand:

loan utilization. If treated banks have demand fall more in distressed real estate markets, then their

customers would be less willing to draw down any unused loan commitments, resulting in a decline

in utilization.

    Tables 6 and 7 repeat the primary difference-in-differences specifications as in the previous two

tables, but using the change in the percentage of commercial loan commitments which are utilized

as the dependent variable. A positive interaction between the treatment variable and house price

growth would indicate that clients of treated banks are less prone to draw down their lines of credit

when house prices decline, indicating potentially larger demand shocks for treated banks.

    Overall, the utilization rate of commercial loan commitments rises when house prices fall. If

falling house prices were to result in a reduction in the availability of credit from local banks, this is
   13 An important caveat in this finding is that construction exposure is correlated with house price movements, so

some of the lending effects of falling house prices may be appearing in the coefficient on construction exposure, which
is much more strongly negative than in the other specifications.
  14 In                               ∂Dˆb             ∂Dˆb
          the context of the model,    ˆ m |T =1
                                      ∂H
                                                   =    ˆ m |T =0
                                                       ∂H



                                                                    16
precisely what would be expected. When less credit is available from other sources, this could make

a firm more likely to lean on existing commitments.

   However, there is little evidence of utilization responding to real estate shocks differently in high

leverage banks. The interaction between the leverage variable and house price growth is significant

at the 5% level in only 2 out of 12 specifications, and in none of the specifications with CBSA-quarter

fixed effects. When it is significant, I find that utilization rises more in leveraged banks when house

prices fall, contrary to what would be likely to happen were demand to be falling disproportionately

in these banks.

   There is more evidence of a difference in utilization when construction exposure is the treatment

variable. I find that utilization rises in construction oriented banks when house prices fall. This
                                              .
consistently holds true when Construction Equity, is the treatment variable, but is less robust
                        .
for High Construction Equity. Again, this indicates that the declines in commercial lending in

construction oriented banks wasn’t due to firms desiring less credit.


1.4.2    Are Results Driven by Loan Losses?

Another way to provide evidence that falling house prices impact lending by impairing loan per-

formance is to include non-performing loans in the specification. If falling house prices resulted

in a contraction in lending because banks took losses on their loan portfolio and forced capital

constrained banks to deleverage, then falling house prices should cease to be important when the

interaction of leverage and non-performing loan rates are controlled for. If banks within distressed

real estate markets cut lending even when their loans continue to pay out, it could indicate that the

contraction reflects something different than a reduced capacity to make loans.

   Tables 8 and 9 support the claim that the declines in commercial lending are indeed due to loan

losses. When I include the non-performing loan rate, bank leverage and their interaction in the

primary specifications presented in Tables 4 and 5, I find that: (1) banks with high non-performing

loans cut lending, (2) this contraction is amplified in leveraged banks and (3) house price growth is

mostly insignificant once loan losses are controlled for.

   For the first finding, banks with more non-performing loans are consistently shown to contract

lending. The first panel of Table 8 adds the non-performing loan rate and its interaction with

High Leverage to the primary difference-in-differences specifications with High Leverage as the

treatment variable. Across the six specifications, banks below the CBSA median in leverage are found

to reduce quarterly lending growth by between 0.24% and 0.29% in response to a 1 percentage point



                                                  17
increase in the non-performing loan rate. The first panel of Table 9 repeats this for the specifications
                         .
with High Construction Equity as the treatment variable. Here, the elasticity lending growth with

respect to non-performing loans is found to run between -0.28 and -0.34 for unleveraged banks. The

coefficient on non-performing loans is significant at the 1% level in all 12 specifications.

    For the second finding, the declines in lending are even greater in leveraged banks. The interaction

between non-performing loans, and the measure of leverage is significant at at least the 5% level in

22 of 24 specifications, and significant at the 10% level in the other two.15 The coefficient on the

interaction of High Leverage and N on-perf orming Loans runs between -0.11 and -0.17. Taking

the mid point of the range of values, a 1% higher non-performing loan rate over the course of a

year would thus reduce C&I lending by roughly 1.16% in unleveraged banks and 1.72% in leveraged

banks.

    Finally, and most relevant to the questions at hand, controlling for non-performing loans causes

house price growth to lose its explanatory power. House price growth is always insignificant. The

interaction of house price growth with the treatment variable is only significant at the 5% level in the
                                             .
two specifications with High Construction Equity as the treatment variable and CBSA-quarter

fixed effects. This isn’t merely caused by inflated standard errors stemming from the inclusion of

correlated regressors, the magnitude of the coefficients on the majority of the housing variables drop

drastically once non-performing loans are controlled for. The interaction effect between house price

growth and the treatment variable drops by over half in 22 of 24 specifications, usually substantially

more.


1.4.3      Effects on Other Lending

How did falling house prices impact the supply of credit in other loan categories? Since C&I lending

only accounts for about 15% of the lending of the banks, ignoring other loan categories gives an

incomplete picture of how falling house prices impacted the supply of credit. Furthermore, since

C&I lending isn’t backed by real estate, there is less of a reason to expect falling house prices to

impact lending for reasons other than the health of local banks. Real estate backed lending may

fall because people or firms experience a decline in the value of their real estate assets and can thus

have less collateral to support borrowing. Additionally, construction lending is likely to fall because

there aren’t good investments to be made. Thus it is more likely that even banks far from their

capital constrain would cut lending, indicating a greater role for demand than I found for commercial
   15 The 24 specifications come from combinations of the following: (leverage,construction)×(indicator,continuous)×(quarter

fixed effect, CBSA-quarter fixed effect, CBSA-quarter fixed effect and bank controls)×(unweighted,weighted).



                                                         18
lending.

   Tables 10-13 test whether leveraged banks disproportionately cut different types of lending in

response to falling house prices. I examine how bank leverage impacts the elasticity of lending

growth with respect to house price growth for total lending (Table 10), lending backed by real estate

(Table 11), construction lending (Table 12) and commercial real estate lending (Table 13). Overall,

there is more evidence of demand driven lending declines when the loan category includes real estate

loans, although the capital crunch channel significantly impacts every type of lending.

   In Table 10, we see that total lending responds more to house price declines in highly leveraged

banks. However, unlike with commercial lending, unleveraged banks cut lending too. The elasticity

of quarterly total lending growth with respect to house price growth is 0.040 for low leverage banks

and 0.097 for leveraged banks. This difference in elasticities isn’t substantially changed by the

inclusion of CBSA-quarter fixed effects, bank controls, or weighting by initial loan volume. Similar

insights are drawn from the use of leverage in its continuous form in the bottom panel. A 15%

decline in house prices over the course of three years would reduce lending by 2.4% for banks below

the median in leverage, and 5.8% for banks above the median.

   In Table 11, we see that the findings for lending backed by real estate is very similar to the

findings for overall lending. The elasticity of quarterly real estate lending growth with respect to

house price growth is 0.042 for low leverage banks and 0.106 for leveraged banks in the unweighted

specification. These elasticities are 0.055 and 0.096 in the weighted specification. Again, using more

conservative fixed effects, additional bank controls, or the continuous measure of leverage don’t

materially change the finding.

   Table 12 shows that the decline in construction lending seems to be more driven by declines in

demand in areas where house prices fall. The elasticity of construction loan growth with respect to

house price growth is 0.303 for low leverage banks and 0.389 for leveraged banks in the unweighted

specification. These elasticities are 0.169 and 0.231 in the weighted specification. Although falling

house prices decrease construction lending significantly more for highly leveraged banks, low leverage

banks contract lending to a strong degree, indicating that the declines predominantly reflected a lack

of desirable construction investments.

   Commercial real estate lending on the other hand follows patters more similar to the non-real

estate backed C&I loans. Table 13 shows that the contractions in lending were predominantly in

leveraged banks. In the unweighted specification, unleveraged banks are found to increase non-

farm non-residential lending by .023% in response to a 1% decline in house prices, while leveraged

banks decrease lending growth by 0.031% in response to a 1% decline in house prices. As many

                                                 19
banks originate very few CRE loans, the weighted specification might be more reflective of changes

in credit. Here we find that the elasticity of CRE lending with respect to house prices is 0.021

for unleveraged banks and 0.063 for leveraged banks, with the difference still being statistically

significant.


1.4.4       How Much of the Decline is Due to Supply Shocks

In this section I attempt to quantify the degree to which banks cut lending due to demand versus

supply factors. Recall that the elasticity of quarterly lending growth in some category G with respect

to last year’s house price growth was decomposed into a credit crunch channel and a demand channel:

                                            ˆb
                                           dL    ∂Lˆ b ∂rb     ∂D ˆb
                                             G        G            G
                                               =             +
                                            ˆm
                                           dH             ˆm
                                                  ∂ rˆb ∂ H    ∂Hˆm
                                                 | {z }        | {z }
                                                   Credit Crunch     Demand
                                                      Channel        Channel


      Between 2007 and 2010, house prices declined on average by 5% per year. Over the course

of 12 quarters, this means that the predicted lending decline due to the credit crunch effect is:
                 ˆb
                ∂L         b                                                                 ˆb
                                                                                            ∂D
                    CI ∂r
.05 × 12 × E(            ˆm )
                 ∂ rˆb ∂ H
                                and the expected decline due to demand is: .05 × 12 × E( ∂ HˆCI ).
                                                                                               m

      In oder to determine these expectations, recall that the coefficients from (1) can be interpreted

as:

                                              ˆ b ∂rb
                                             ∂L                     ˆ b ∂rb
                                                                   ∂L
                                                 G                     G
                                    β1,G =              |     −               |
                                                     ˆ m T =1
                                             ∂ rˆb ∂ H                     ˆ m T =0
                                                                   ∂ rˆb ∂ H
                                              ˆ b ∂rb
                                             ∂L                    ∂D ˆb
                                                 G                    G
                                    β2,G   =            |     +
                                                     ˆ m T =0
                                             ∂ rˆb ∂ H              ˆm
                                                                   ∂H

      Since we have two equations and three unknowns, I need to make an additional assumption in

order to identify how the regression coefficients map into these elasticities. Note that the parame-

terization in equation 8 implies that:

                                    ˆ b ∂rb
                                   ∂L                           ˆ b ∂rb
                                                      ηo + ηT ∂ L
                                       G                          CI
                                              |T =1 =        ×            |
                                           ˆm
                                   ∂ rˆb ∂ H             η0            ˆ m T =0
                                                               ∂ rˆb ∂ H
                                                      | {z }
                                                        1+χ


                           ηT
      Denoting the ratio   η0    ≡ χ, one can solve this system of 3 equations for all of the elasticities of

interest as a function of the regression coefficients and χ.




                                                         20
                                               
                                                 ˆb
                                                 ∂D                β1,G
                                               
                                               
                                                 ˆ
                                                 ∂H
                                                    G
                                                      = β2,G −      χ
                                                m
                                               
                                               
                                                  ˆb
                                                 ∂L      b
                                                     G ∂r              1                                                    (1.10)
                                                        ˆ m |T =0 =
                                                 ∂ rˆb ∂ H             χ β1,G
                                               
                                               
                                                   ˆ b ∂r b
                                               
                                                ∂ LG                  1+χ
                                               
                                                         ˆ |T =1 =      χ β1,G
                                               
                                                 ∂ rˆb ∂ H
                                                         m


                                                                                     ˆb
                                                                                    ∂D                      β1,G
   Thus the decline in lending due to falling demand is: .6 × E( ∂ Hˆ G ) = .6 × (β2,G −                     χ ).    Since half
                                                                                       m

of the banks are high leverage and half low leverage, the decline due to the credit crunch channel is:
           ˆ b ∂r b
          ∂L                      1+.5χ
.6 × E(       G
                  ˆm )
          ∂ rˆb ∂ H
                         = .6 ×     χ β1,G .

   To bound these effects, one must make an assumption regarding the value of χ, which parameter-

izes how much more important equity shocks are to leveraged banks than unleveraged banks. A high

χ means that unleveraged banks minimally respond to equity shocks, meaning that the coefficient
   ˆ m mostly reflects the influence on falling house prices on demand. Low values of χ mean that
on H

even low leverage banks are sensitive to equity shocks, and thus give larger predicted supply effects.

   Consider two polar sets of assumptions to bound potential supply and demand effects. First,

lets make the assumption that maximizes the predicted demand effect. Specifically, assume that
                                                                                                         ˆ b ∂r b
                                                                                                        ∂L
low leverage banks can take losses without it impacting the cost of lending (                                   ˆ m |T =0   = 0).
                                                                                                            G
                                                                                                        ∂ rˆb ∂ H

This corresponds with χ = ∞, making the credit crunch channel equal to: .3β1,G and the demand

channel equal to .6β2,G .

   Second, assume that the entire contraction in C&I lending was due to supply. Based on equation
                                                                       β1,CI        6.32
10 and the findings in Table 4, this implies that χ =                  β2,CI    =   2.02 .   I can then use this χ to assess

how supply and demand shocks impacted lending in other categories.

   Using the estimated coefficients from Table 4, and Tables 10-13 gives the following estimates of

how the 15% decline in house prices in the US impacted bank lending through the credit crunch

and demand channels under the two assumptions regarding χ. Note that for construction loans and

CRE loans I use the weighted specification, as these types of lending are more concentrated in fewer

banks, whereas real estate lending in more generally an important part of a bank’s portfolio.




                                                              21
                       Demand Friendly Assumption               Supply Friendly Assumption
                                                                                6.32
                                   χ=∞                                     χ=   2.02

      Loan Type     Demand Channel       Supply Channel      Demand Channel      Supply Channel

      Commercial           1.2%                1.9%                0.0%                3.1%

        Overall            2.4%                1.7%                1.3%                2.8%

      Real Estate          2.5%                1.9%                1.3%                 3.1

    Construction          10.1%                1.9%                9.0%                3.0%

         CRE               1.3%                1.3%                0.5%                2.1%

   Under the demand friendly assumption, which attributes any lending declines in unleveraged

banks as the result of declining loan demand, we typically have falling house prices resulting in a

contraction in the supply of credit accounting for slightly less than a 2% decline across the different

lending categories. Under the supply friendly assumptions, which assume that the decline in com-

mercial lending was entirely a supply side phenomenon, we have falling house prices explaining a

roughly 3% decline in lending. Although this may sound small, total lending in commercial banks

was around $7 trillion before the crises, thus this implies a supply driven contraction of between

$140-210 billion.



1.5      Conclusion

One of the most salient features of the Great Recession was the strong relationship between falling

house prices and the local employment losses. While these housing declines were undoubtedly central

to the economic turmoil, the exact mechanism is unclear. Were the employment losses a consequence

of the loss in housing wealth and a resultant decline in consumption? Were they a consequence of

the extreme losses in construction and related industries? Were the rash of bank failures a cause or

a consequence the economic turmoil?

   This paper takes an important step in evaluating these questions, namely I ask whether falling

house prices impacted the supply of credit. I show that falling house prices didn’t uniformly impact

the commercial lending of local banks, instead lending fell in the banks for whom falling house

prices would have resulted in the greatest contraction in the capacity to lend. Specifically, only

construction oriented banks and leveraged banks reduced lending in areas with falling house prices.

   However, one must be cautious in interpreting this result as it ignores the sort of adjustments

which should occur in equilibrium. I have shown that lending predominantly fell due to supply

shocks instead of demand shocks at the bank level. However, a contraction in one bank may increase

                                                  22
the demand for loans from another. With perfect banking markets, firms would move out of capital

constrained banks and into the banks in a position to lend more cheaply. Overall lending would fall

due to demand, and the differentials between banks would be uninformative regarding the aggregate

availability of credit.

   Despite this cause for caution, there are good reasons to believe that substituting away from

a bank is costly. Chodorow-Reich (2014) shows that even for the relatively large firms borrowing

from very large banks, banking relationships are sticky. A shock to a firm’s bank was shown to

have a large impact on employment decision of firms who didn’t have access to the bond market.

Given that the customers of the small single market banks in my sample disproportionately make

information sensitive loans to small opaque firms (Berger et al., 2005), it is unlikely that they’d be

more able to substitute away from a banking relationship than the firms active in syndicated loan

markets appearing in the sample in Chodorow-Reich (2014).

   In short, this large disruption in the supply of lending at the bank level has the potential to

disrupt the economy, but it is difficult to quantify the degree with this approach. This will be the

goal of the next chapter.




                                                 23
1.6         Appendix

1.6.1        Figures

 M C Lending                                                                M C Lending
                                      M C 2 M C1                                                M C 2 M C1




      rf                                                                       rf
                                                MR                                                                      MR
                                                            Lending                                                                   Lending
                                    L?1 = L?2                                                    L?2     L?1

              (a) Supply Shock: Low Leverage                                           (b) Supply Shock: High Leverage
 M C Lending                                                                M C Lending
                                                MC                                                  MC




      rf                                                                       rf
                                   M R2         M R1                                                          M R2      M R1
                                                            Lending                                                                   Lending
                            L?2         L?1                                                       L?1 = L?2

             (c) Demand Shock: Low Leverage                                           (d) Demand Shock: High Leverage

                                  Figure 1.1: Lending Elasticities: By Bank Leverage
Notes: This figure demonstrates the differential effect of bank leverage on the responsiveness of bank lending to a supply versus
a demand shock. Deposits are supplied inelastically at the market rate rf , but banks have a leverage constraint so that lending
cannot be greater than a certain multiple of their equity, causing the supply curve to go vertical. The top panels show that a
decline in equity (a leftward shift of the supply curve) only impacts lending if a bank is on its capital constraint. The bottom
panels show that a decline in demand only impacts lending if a bank is not on its capital constraint. This means that the empirical
finding that falling house prices result in a contraction in lending for leveraged banks implies that these declines predominantly
impact the supply of lending.




                                                                       24
1.6.2     Tables

                                       Table 1.1: Summary Statistics

                                                             Mean     Standard         Percentile        Obs
                                                                      Deviation      25th    75th
   Primary Variables
   Weighted by C&I Lending
      House P rice .
                   Growth (annual)                           -0.020     0.062       -0.042    0.014     68895
      Construction Equity                                     0.995     0.787        0.344     1.475    68895
      Leverage                                               11.145     2.084        9.853    12.577    68895
      ∆ln(C&I Loans)                                         -0.001     0.087       -0.044    0.044     67739
   Unweighted
      House P rice .
                   Growth (annual)                           -0.010     0.050       -0.026    0.017     70639
      Construction Equity                                     0.697     0.755        0.116     1.022    70639
      Leverage                                               10.344     2.369       8.654     12.052    70639
      ∆ln(C&I Loans)                                         0.002      0.114       -0.053     0.056    67945
   Other Outcome Variables (unweighted)
   Non-performing Loans (%)
      Overall                                                0.022      0.033       0.004     0.028     70430
      Real Estate                                            0.024      0.036       0.003     0.031     70082
      Construction                                           0.058      0.122       0.000     0.059     65198
      M ultif amily Residential                              0.020      0.091       0.000     0.000     52782
      HELOC                                                  0.009      0.047       0.000     0.003     51241
      Commercial and Industrial                              0.020      0.043       0.000     0.022     69119
      Individuals                                            0.009      0.025       0.000     0.009     69899
   Quarterly Growth Rates
      Assets                                                 0.008      0.035       -0.012    0.030     69912
      Equity                                                 0.006      0.049       -0.008    0.028     69511
      T otal Lending                                         0.008      0.041       -0.015    0.029     69628
      Real Estate Lending                                    0.010      0.045       -0.015    0.031     69155
      Construction Lending                                   -0.011     0.235       -0.102    0.077     63374
      CRE Lending                                            0.015      0.084       -0.024    0.047     68219
      M ultif amily Residential Lending                      0.020      0.207       -0.024    0.026     51058
      Home Equity Lines of Credit                            0.020      0.143       -0.031    0.063     49915
      Lending to Individuals                                 -0.011     0.098       -0.052    0.027     68827
   Credit Utilization (%)
      ∆CI Loan U tilization                                  0.001      0.062       -0.027    0.030     68440
Notes: This table reports summary statistics of the main bank-quarter level variables in this paper. The most
important explanatory variables (leverage, construction exposure and annual local house price appreciation) and
the key outcome variable (quarterly commercial lending growth) are summarized both as weighted by the level of
commercial lending at the end of the previous quarter and unweighted. As in the regressions, I drop any observation
more than five standard deviations above the mean in commercial lending when weighting. Other outcome variables
pertaining to loan performance, balance sheet growth, or credit utilization are unweighted.




                                                        25
                                               Table 1.2: Housing Declines and Loan Non-performance

                                      (1)              (2)                    (3)              (4)               (5)              (6)           (7)
                                     Total       Non-Construction         Construction      Commercial        Individual         CRE         Multifamily
      Panel 1: Unweighted
      House P rice Growth           -0.155∗∗          -0.0798∗∗              -0.496∗∗         -0.0484∗∗         -0.0172∗      -0.0529∗∗        -0.127∗∗
                                    (0.0197)           (0.0129)              (0.0613)          (0.0110)        (0.00708)       (0.0126)        (0.0347)

      Constant                      0.0209∗∗           0.0166∗∗              0.0527∗∗         0.0195∗∗         0.00864∗∗       0.0214∗∗         0.0188∗∗
                                   (0.00107)          (0.000680)            (0.00348)        (0.000636)       (0.000284)      (0.000703)       (0.00142)
      Observations                   70430               70430                65198             69119            69899           69479           52782
      R2                              0.106              0.074                 0.093            0.019            0.004           0.031            0.011

      Panel 2: Weighted by Level of Lending
      House P rice Growth -0.136∗∗          -0.0755∗∗                        -0.431∗∗         -0.0412∗∗         -0.0207       -0.0525∗∗        -0.0779+
26




                             (0.0292)        (0.0204)                        (0.0852)          (0.0121)        (0.0144)        (0.0158)        (0.0464)

      Constant                      0.0246∗∗           0.0170∗∗              0.0753∗∗         0.0175∗∗        0.00828∗∗        0.0200∗∗         0.0248∗∗
                                   (0.00230)          (0.00123)             (0.00715)        (0.000724)       (0.00107)       (0.00130)        (0.00365)
      Observations                   70186              70174                 64452             68861           69764           69047            51856
      R2                              0.128              0.117                 0.236            0.055           0.015            0.102            0.026
      Quarter Fixed Effect             Yes                Yes                   Yes              Yes             Yes              Yes              Yes
       Standard errors in parentheses
       + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

     Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of quarterly bank level non-performing loan rates for different types of loans on local house
     price growth and quarter fixed effects. The dependent variable is the non-performing loan rate overall in (1), on loans besides construction and land
     development loans in (2), construction and land development loans in (3), commercial loans in (4), loans to individuals in (5), loans backed by non-farm
     non-residential properties in (6), and loans backed by multifamily properties in (7). The non-performing loan rate is the percentage of the value of
     loans which are 90 days past due or not accruing interest. The first panel is estimated with OLS. The second panel weights by the level of lending in
     the given category at the end of the previous quarter, dropping observations more than 5 standard deviations above the mean in the lending category.
     The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes banks which hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA or county. Standard errors are clustered by
     CBSA/county.
                                            Table 1.3: Housing Declines and Loan Growth: By Loan Type

                                          (1)           (2)           (3)           (4)          (5)           (6)           (7)              (8)
                                         Assets        Equity      Securities     Lending        C&I           RE        Construction        CRE
           Panel 1: Unweighted
           House P rice Growth           0.0481∗∗      0.124∗∗      0.0511∗∗      0.0684∗∗     0.0569∗∗     0.0767∗∗         0.350∗∗       0.00788
                                        (0.00715)     (0.0129)      (0.0178)      (0.0116)     (0.0144)     (0.0131)        (0.0297)       (0.0117)
           Observations                   69912         69511        68223         69628        67945        69155            63374         68219
           R2                              0.024        0.109         0.008         0.075        0.017        0.057           0.022          0.009

           Panel 2: Weighted by Initial Level
           House P rice Growth 0.0436∗∗ 0.0771∗∗                                  0.0686∗∗     0.0697∗∗     0.0820∗∗         0.212∗∗       0.0446∗∗
27




                                                                    -0.00712
                                   (0.0166) (0.0272)                (0.0401)      (0.0212)     (0.0146)     (0.0150)        (0.0417)       (0.0121)
           Observations             69790     69347                  68159         69402        67739        68928            63118         67855
           R2                        0.033    0.072                   0.017         0.128        0.054        0.121           0.120          0.031
           Quarter Fixed Effect       Yes      Yes                     Yes           Yes          Yes          Yes             Yes            Yes
           Standard errors in parentheses
           + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

     Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of quarterly bank level growth rates for different balance sheet variables on local house price
     growth and quarter fixed effects. The dependent variable is the growth rate of assets in (1), equity in (2), securities in (3), total lending in (4),
     commercial lending in (5), lending backed by real estate in (6), construction and lend development lending in (7), and lending backed by non-farm
     non-residential properties in (8). The first panel is estimated with OLS. The second panel weights by the initial level of the balance sheet variable
     at the end of the previous quarter, dropping observations more than 5 standard deviations above the mean. The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and
     includes banks which hold over 50% of their 2006 deposits in one CBSA or county. Standard errors are clustered by CBSA/county.
              Table 1.4: Housing Declines and Commercial Lending Growth: By Leverage

                                    (1)                (2)           (3)          (4)          (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for High Leverage
 High Leverage                  -0.00227∗           -0.00233∗     -0.00235+    0.000626     -0.000845    -0.000652
                                (0.00105)           (0.00118)     (0.00122)    (0.00208)    (0.00224)    (0.00241)

 House P rice Growth                    0.0202                                  0.0383∗
                                       (0.0137)                                 (0.0182)

 High Leverage ×                       0.0632∗∗      0.0652∗∗      0.0653∗∗     0.0413∗     0.0547∗∗      0.0528∗∗
 House P rice Growth                   (0.0204)      (0.0230)      (0.0229)     (0.0185)    (0.0171)      (0.0181)
 Observations                           56214         56214         56214        56013       56013         56013
 R2                                      0.020         0.245         0.246       0.065        0.324         0.325

 Panel 2: Leverage
 Leverage                             -0.000866∗∗   -0.000815∗    -0.000874∗    -0.000448    -0.000568    -0.000575
                                       (0.000250)   (0.000331)    (0.000355)   (0.000627)   (0.000677)   (0.000739)

 House P rice Growth                   -0.235∗∗                                  -0.0660
                                       (0.0418)                                 (0.0510)

 Leverage ×                             0.0268∗∗     0.0203∗∗      0.0205∗∗     0.0119∗      0.0118+       0.0116
 House P rice Growth                   (0.00414)    (0.00591)     (0.00589)    (0.00471)    (0.00699)     (0.00718)
 Observations                            66672        66672         66672        66468        66468         66468
 R2                                       0.020        0.290         0.291       0.062        0.360         0.360
 Quarter Fixed Effect                      Yes          No            No          Yes           No           No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                 No           Yes           Yes         No           Yes           Yes
 Weighted                                  No           No            No          Yes          Yes           Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of quarterly bank level commercial and industrial lending
growth on bank leverage, CBSA house price growth and their interaction. Leverage is the ratio of tangible assets to
tangible equity. In first panel, I use an indicator for whether leverage is above the median for the CBSA-quarter. The
second panel uses leverage in its continuous form, winsorized at the 5% level. Columns 1 & 4 include quarter fixed
effects, while Columns 2,3,5 & 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed effects. Columns 1-3 are unweighted, while columns 4-6
weight by the size of the bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the previous quarter. The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and
includes bank holding companies which hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA or county, dropping observations
in the highest or lowest percentile of lending growth. The weighted regressions additionally drop banks 5 standard
deviations above the mean in commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered by CBSA/county.




                                                             28
     Table 1.5: Housing Declines and Commercial Lending Growth: By Construction Exposure

                                      (1)                (2)           (3)          (4)           (5)          (6)
 Panel 1: High Construction
                    .       Exposure
 High Construction Equity         -0.000571           -0.000597    -0.000577      0.00331      0.00283       0.00323
                                 (0.000988)           (0.00112)    (0.00126)     (0.00262)    (0.00239)     (0.00259)

 House P rice Growth                     0.00117                                  0.00928
                                         (0.0152)                                 (0.0275)
                   .
 High Construction Equity ×               0.101∗∗       0.108∗∗      0.111∗∗       0.104∗∗      0.120∗∗      0.118∗∗
 House P rice Growth                     (0.0196)      (0.0222)     (0.0221)      (0.0321)     (0.0332)     (0.0321)
 Observations                              55766         55766        55766         55575        55575        55575
 R2                                        0.020         0.246        0.247         0.066        0.328        0.329

 Panel 2: Construction
              .        to Equity Ratio
 Construction Equity              -0.00321∗∗           -0.00175    -0.00244∗     -0.00251+     -0.00160      -0.00219
                                  (0.000650)          (0.00109)    (0.00122)     (0.00128)    (0.00204)     (0.00251)

 House P rice Growth                    -0.0551∗∗                                 0.00617
                                         (0.0196)                                 (0.0235)
              .
 Construction Equity ×                  0.0773∗∗      0.0814∗∗      0.0821∗∗     0.0459∗∗      0.0739∗∗     0.0739∗∗
 House P rice Growth                    (0.0148)      (0.0177)      (0.0176)     (0.0155)      (0.0197)     (0.0196)
 Observations                            66672         66672         66672        66468         66468        66468
 R2                                       0.020         0.290         0.291        0.063         0.361        0.361
 Quarter Fixed Effect                      Yes           No            No           Yes           No           No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                 No            Yes           Yes          No            Yes          Yes
 Weighted                                  No            No            No           Yes           Yes          Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of quarterly bank level commercial and industrial lending growth
on bank construction exposure, CBSA house price growth and their interaction. Construction exposure is the ratio
of bank construction lending to equity. In first panel, I use an indicator for whether construction exposure is above
the median for the CBSA-quarter. The second panel uses construction exposure in its continuous form, winsorized
at the 5% level. Columns 1 & 4 include quarter fixed effects, while Columns 2,3,5 & 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed
effects. Columns 1-3 are unweighted, while columns 4-6 weight by the size of the bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the
previous quarter. The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes bank holding companies which hold over 50% of
their deposits in one CBSA or county, dropping observations in the highest or lowest percentile of lending growth. The
weighted regressions additionally drop banks 5 standard deviations above the mean in commercial lending. Standard
errors are clustered by CBSA/county.




                                                          29
              Table 1.6: Housing Declines and Commercial Loan Utilization: By Leverage

                                     (1)               (2)           (3)          (4)          (5)            (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for High Leverage
 High Leverage                   -0.000108          -0.0000898     -0.000259    -0.000307   0.0000111      -0.000226
                                (0.000475)          (0.000537)    (0.000551)   (0.000759)   (0.000855)    (0.000931)

 House P rice Growth                   -0.0260∗∗                                 -0.0124
                                       (0.00686)                                (0.0109)

 High Leverage ×                        0.00318      0.00399       0.00447      -0.00395     0.00894        0.0117
 House P rice Growth                   (0.00702)    (0.00793)     (0.00799)    (0.00880)     (0.0118)     (0.00976)
 Observations                            57818        57818         57818        57685        57685         57685
 R2                                      0.006        0.240         0.241         0.014       0.293         0.297

 Panel 2: Leverage
 Leverage                              0.0000257    0.0000760     0.0000726    -0.000253+    -0.000161     -0.000211
                                      (0.0000968)   (0.000148)    (0.000154)   (0.000147)   (0.000163)    (0.000200)

 House P rice Growth                   0.00803                                   0.0485
                                       (0.0170)                                 (0.0347)

 Leverage ×                            -0.00323∗     -0.00322      -0.00299    -0.00590∗    -0.000399    0.00000137
 House P rice Growth                   (0.00148)    (0.00218)     (0.00219)    (0.00268)    (0.00261)     (0.00238)
 Observations                            68440        68440         68440        68304        68304         68304
 R2                                      0.006         0.292         0.293       0.014        0.337         0.340
 Quarter Fixed Effect                     Yes           No            No          Yes           No           No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                 No           Yes           Yes          No          Yes           Yes
 Weighted                                  No           No            No          Yes          Yes           Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of changes in quarterly bank level commercial and industrial
loan utilization on bank leverage, CBSA house price growth and their interaction. Leverage is the ratio of tangible
assets to tangible equity. In first panel, I use an indicator for whether leverage is above the median for the CBSA-
quarter. The second panel uses leverage in its continuous form, winsorized at the 5% level. Columns 1 & 4 include
quarter fixed effects, while Columns 2,3,5 & 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed effects. Columns 1-3 are unweighted, while
columns 4-6 weight by the size of the bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the previous quarter. The sample runs from 2007
to 2010 and includes bank holding companies which hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA or county, dropping
observations in the highest or lowest percentile of ∆C&I U tilizationb,m,q . The weighted regressions additionally drop
banks 5 standard deviations above the mean in commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered by CBSA/county.




                                                             30
     Table 1.7: Housing Declines and Commercial Loan Utilization: By Construction Exposure

                                       (1)          (2)               (3)           (4)           (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for
                      . High Construction  Exposure
 High Construction Equity           0.00170∗∗   0.00178∗∗          0.00170∗∗     0.00192∗     0.00320∗∗      0.00222∗∗
                                   (0.000351) (0.000401)          (0.000416)    (0.000812)    (0.00124)     (0.000759)

 House P rice Growth                    -0.0163∗                                  -0.0101
                                       (0.00634)                                 (0.00921)
                   .
 High Construction Equity ×             -0.0157∗     -0.0152+       -0.0137       -0.0196     -0.000247      0.00246
 House P rice Growth                   (0.00796)     (0.00902)     (0.00897)     (0.0122)      (0.0213)      (0.0207)
 Observations                            57320         57320         57320         57190        57190         57190
 R2                                       0.006        0.240         0.240         0.015        0.298         0.301

 Panel 2: Construction
              .        Lending to Equity Ratio
 Construction Equity               0.00176∗∗   0.00163∗∗           0.00144∗∗     0.00119∗      0.00218∗∗     0.000996
                                  (0.000237) (0.000375)           (0.000384)    (0.000498)    (0.000769)    (0.000806)

 House P rice Growth                  0.0000881                                   0.0209
                                      (0.00771)                                  (0.0149)
              .
 Construction Equity ×                 -0.0169∗∗     -0.0179∗∗     -0.0174∗∗     -0.0309∗∗      -0.0187∗      -0.0191∗
 House P rice Growth                   (0.00452)     (0.00612)     (0.00626)     (0.00761)     (0.00863)     (0.00871)
 Observations                            68440         68440         68440         68304         68304         68304
 R2                                      0.007         0.292         0.293         0.016          0.338         0.341
 Quarter Fixed Effect                     Yes            No            No           Yes            No            No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                 No           Yes           Yes            No            Yes           Yes
 Weighted                                  No            No            No           Yes            Yes           Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of changes in quarterly bank level commercial and industrial
loan utilization on bank construction exposure, CBSA house price growth and their interaction. Construction exposure
is the ratio of bank construction lending to equity. In first panel, I use an indicator for whether construction exposure
is above the median for the CBSA-quarter. The second panel uses construction exposure in its continuous form,
winsorized at the 5% level. Columns 1 & 4 include quarter fixed effects, while Columns 2,3,5 & 6 include CBSA-
quarter fixed effects. Columns 1-3 are unweighted, while columns 4-6 weight by the size of the bank’s C&I loan
portfolio in the previous quarter. The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes bank holding companies which
hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA or county, dropping observations in the highest or lowest percentile of
∆C&I U tilizationb,m,q . The weighted regressions additionally drop banks 5 standard deviations above the mean in
commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered by CBSA/county.




                                                           31
             Table 1.8: Are Results Driven By Real Estate Losses: Leverage Specifications

                                   (1)                (2)            (3)           (4)            (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for High Leverage
 High Leverage                   0.00135            0.00105      0.000792       0.00553∗        0.00381       0.00393
                                (0.00130)          (0.00148)     (0.00155)      (0.00282)      (0.00298)     (0.00327)

 House P rice Growth                   -0.00181                                   0.0163
                                       (0.0186)                                  (0.0211)

 High Leverage ×                       -0.00558     0.00166       0.00150         0.0102        0.0189        0.0180
 House P rice Growth                   (0.0217)     (0.0241)      (0.0239)       (0.0214)      (0.0220)      (0.0217)

 N on-perf orming Loans                -0.293∗∗     -0.265∗∗      -0.278∗∗       -0.286∗∗      -0.242∗∗      -0.252∗∗
                                       (0.0443)     (0.0577)      (0.0591)       (0.0706)      (0.0765)      (0.0788)

 High Leverage ×                       -0.166∗∗     -0.157∗∗      -0.157∗∗        -0.136∗       -0.130∗       -0.137∗
 N on-perf orming Loans                (0.0396)     (0.0461)      (0.0471)       (0.0613)      (0.0639)      (0.0632)
 Observations                           57317        57317         57317           57114         57114         57114
 R2                                      0.028        0.241         0.243          0.073         0.323         0.324

 Panel 2: Leverage
 Leverage                              -0.000150    -0.000169     -0.000269     0.00109        0.000637      0.000636
                                      (0.000316)   (0.000427)    (0.000442)    (0.000940)     (0.000877)     (0.00103)

 House P rice Growth                    -0.0641                                 -0.00608
                                       (0.0533)                                 (0.0586)

 Leverage ×                            0.00549      0.00126       0.00151        0.00255        0.00491       0.00477
 House P rice Growth                  (0.00490)    (0.00633)     (0.00623)      (0.00532)      (0.00523)     (0.00539)

 N on-perf orming Loans                 -0.0608     -0.00461      -0.0166        -0.0353        -0.0208       -0.0231
                                       (0.0849)      (0.107)      (0.107)        (0.160)        (0.145)       (0.144)

 Leverage ×                           -0.0287∗∗    -0.0307∗∗     -0.0308∗∗       -0.0301∗      -0.0268∗      -0.0280∗
 N on-perf orming Loans               (0.00783)    (0.00953)     (0.00949)       (0.0135)      (0.0122)      (0.0123)
 Observations                           67945        67945         67945          67739         67739         67739
 R2                                     0.028        0.286         0.287           0.071         0.361         0.362
 Quarter Fixed Effect                    Yes           No            No             Yes           No            No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                No          Yes           Yes             No            Yes           Yes
 Weighted                                 No           No            No             Yes           Yes           Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of quarterly bank holding company level commercial and
industrial lending growth on MSA level house price growth, the bank level non-performing loan rate, and the interaction
of these variables with bank leverage. Leverage is the ratio of tangible assets to tangible equity. In first panel, I use
an indicator for whether leverage is above the median for the CBSA-quarter. The second panel uses leverage in
its continuous form, winsorized at the 5% level. Columns 1 & 4 include quarter fixed effects, while Columns 2,3,5
& 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed effects. Columns 1-3 are unweighted, while columns 4-6 weight by the size of the
bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the previous quarter. The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes bank holding
companies which hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA or county, dropping observations in the highest or
lowest percentile of lending growth. The weighted regressions additionally drop banks 5 standard deviations above
the mean in commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered by CBSA/county.




                                                            32
          Table 1.9: Are Results Driven By Real Estate Losses: Construction Specifications

                                     (1)        (2)                   (3)          (4)          (5)          (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for
                      .High Construction Exposure
 High Construction Equity          0.0023∗    0.0019                0.0016      0.0065∗      0.0065∗∗     0.0060∗
                                  (0.0011)   (0.0013)              (0.0014)     (0.0030)     (0.0024)     (0.0025)

 House P rice Growth                     -0.0192                                 -0.0081
                                        (0.0184)                                (0.0290)
                   .
 High Construction Equity ×              0.0320       0.0410+      0.0441+       0.0491      0.0849∗      0.0821∗
 House P rice Growth                    (0.0219)      (0.0247)     (0.0244)     (0.0358)     (0.0382)     (0.0374)

 N on-perf orming Loans                 -0.3026∗∗    -0.2718∗∗    -0.2828∗∗    -0.3126∗∗     -0.2582∗∗    -0.2614∗∗
                                         (0.0455)     (0.0612)     (0.0624)     (0.0673)      (0.0747)     (0.0784)

 High Leverage                           0.0002        0.0001       0.0000       0.0035       0.0019       0.0024
                                        (0.0014)      (0.0016)     (0.0016)     (0.0028)     (0.0030)     (0.0033)

 High Leverage ×                        -0.1516∗∗    -0.1433∗∗    -0.1437∗∗     -0.1137∗     -0.1147+     -0.1236+
 N on-perf orming Loans                  (0.0383)     (0.0453)     (0.0462)     (0.0556)     (0.0674)     (0.0678)
 Observations                             53738        53738        53738        53548         53548        53548
 R2                                       0.029         0.252        0.253        0.076        0.329        0.330

 Panel 2: Construction
              .        Lending to Equity Ratio
 Construction Equity              0.0021∗∗     0.0030∗              0.0020      0.0023∗       0.0026       0.0017
                                   (0.0007)   (0.0013)             (0.0014)     (0.0011)     (0.0019)     (0.0023)

 House P rice Growth                     -0.0232                                 0.0258
                                        (0.0206)                                (0.0272)
              .
 Construction Equity ×                   0.0183        0.0182       0.0186       -0.0022      0.0334       0.0320
 House P rice Growth                    (0.0141)      (0.0217)     (0.0217)     (0.0174)     (0.0222)     (0.0221)

 N on-perf orming Loans                  -0.0467       -0.0075      -0.0161      -0.0197      -0.0036      -0.0048
                                        (0.0791)      (0.1012)     (0.1018)     (0.1470)     (0.1322)     (0.1269)

 Leverage                                -0.0003       -0.0004      -0.0004      0.0009       0.0004       0.0005
                                        (0.0003)      (0.0004)     (0.0004)     (0.0010)     (0.0009)     (0.0011)

 Leverage ×                             -0.0309∗∗    -0.0315∗∗    -0.0313∗∗    -0.0332∗∗     -0.0286∗     -0.0293∗∗
 N on-perf orming Loans                  (0.0074)     (0.0092)     (0.0092)     (0.0123)     (0.0113)      (0.0110)
 Observations                             67945        67945        67945        67739        67739         67739
 R2                                       0.028         0.286        0.288       0.072         0.361        0.362
 Quarter Fixed Effect                      Yes           No           No          Yes           No            No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                  No           Yes          Yes          No           Yes          Yes
 Weighted                                   No           No           No          Yes           Yes          Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of quarterly bank holding company level commercial and
industrial lending growth on the interaction between bank exposure to construction loans and MSA house price
growth and the interaction between the bank non-performing loan rate and leverage. Construction exposure is the
ratio of bank construction lending to equity and leverage is the ratio of tangible assets to tangible equity. In first
panel, I use an indicator for whether construction exposure or leverage is above the median for the CBSA-quarter.
The second panel uses construction exposure and leverage in their continuous forms, winsorized at the 5% level.
Columns 1 & 4 include quarter fixed effects, while Columns 2,3,5 & 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed effects. Columns
1-3 are unweighted, while columns 4-6 weight by the size of the bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the previous quarter.
The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes bank holding companies which hold over 50% of their deposits in one
CBSA or county, dropping observations in the highest or lowest percentile of lending growth. The weighted regressions
additionally drop banks 5 standard deviations above the mean in commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered
by CBSA/county.                                          33
                        Table 1.10: Housing Declines and Total Lending: By Leverage

                                   (1)                (2)             (3)           (4)           (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for High Leverage
 High Leverage                 -0.00304∗∗          -0.00307∗∗      -0.00295∗∗   -0.00183+      -0.00241∗     -0.00217∗
                               (0.000558)          (0.000630)      (0.000679)   (0.000936)    (0.000953)    (0.000966)

 House P rice Growth                  0.0404∗∗                                    0.0328
                                      (0.0130)                                   (0.0298)

 High Leverage ×                      0.0565∗∗     0.0559∗∗        0.0543∗∗      0.0592∗∗      0.0505∗∗      0.0522∗∗
 House P rice Growth                  (0.0116)     (0.0130)        (0.0128)      (0.0201)      (0.0193)      (0.0201)
 Observations                          58872        58872           58872         58651         58651         58651
 R2                                     0.079        0.321           0.324         0.136         0.393         0.397

 Panel 2: Leverage
 Leverage                             -0.00100∗∗   -0.00105∗∗      -0.00113∗∗   -0.000884∗∗   -0.000875∗∗   -0.000842∗∗
                                      (0.000147)   (0.000181)      (0.000200)    (0.000238)    (0.000284)    (0.000296)

 House P rice Growth                   -0.139∗∗                                  -0.0972∗∗
                                       (0.0295)                                   (0.0350)

 Leverage ×                            0.0198∗∗     0.0149∗∗        0.0144∗∗      0.0152∗∗     0.00956∗       0.0103∗∗
 House P rice Growth                  (0.00283)    (0.00356)       (0.00344)     (0.00310)     (0.00379)     (0.00352)
 Observations                           69628        69628           69628         69402         69402         69402
 R2                                      0.083        0.362           0.365         0.139        0.419          0.423
 Quarter Fixed Effect                     Yes          No              No            Yes          No             No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                No           Yes             Yes           No           Yes            Yes
 Weighted                                 No           No              No            Yes          Yes            Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of quarterly bank level lending growth on bank leverage, CBSA
house price growth and their interaction. Leverage is the ratio of tangible assets to tangible equity. In first panel,
I use an indicator for whether leverage is above the median for the CBSA-quarter. The second panel uses leverage
in its continuous form, winsorized at the 5% level. Columns 1 & 4 include quarter fixed effects, while Columns 2,3,5
& 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed effects. Columns 1-3 are unweighted, while columns 4-6 weight by the size of the
bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the previous quarter. The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes bank holding
companies which hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA or county, dropping observations in the highest or
lowest percentile of lending growth. The weighted regressions additionally drop banks 5 standard deviations above
the mean in commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered by CBSA/county.




                                                              34
                   Table 1.11: Housing Declines and Real Estate Lending: By Leverage

                                    (1)                 (2)            (3)          (4)          (5)          (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for High Leverage
 High Leverage                  -0.00220∗∗          -0.00226∗∗     -0.00198∗∗    -0.00262∗∗   -0.00291∗∗   -0.00260∗∗
                                (0.000614)          (0.000695)     (0.000735)    (0.000923)   (0.000929)   (0.000974)

 House P rice Growth                   0.0424∗                                   0.0551∗∗
                                       (0.0165)                                  (0.0187)

 High Leverage ×                       0.0633∗∗      0.0637∗∗       0.0586∗∗     0.0404∗∗     0.0517∗∗     0.0464∗∗
 House P rice Growth                   (0.0132)      (0.0148)       (0.0142)     (0.0140)     (0.0176)     (0.0173)
 Observations                           58422         58422          58422        58202        58202        58202
 R2                                      0.061         0.277          0.288        0.128        0.370        0.383

 Panel 2: Leverage
 Leverage                             -0.000742∗∗   -0.000817∗∗    -0.000884∗∗   -0.00101∗∗   -0.00101∗∗   -0.00100∗∗
                                       (0.000158)    (0.000198)     (0.000213)   (0.000250)   (0.000305)   (0.000306)

 House P rice Growth                   -0.155∗∗                                    -0.0678
                                       (0.0317)                                   (0.0532)

 Leverage ×                             0.0220∗∗      0.0183∗∗       0.0168∗∗     0.0131∗      0.0110+     0.00984+
 House P rice Growth                   (0.00276)     (0.00328)      (0.00317)    (0.00534)    (0.00662)    (0.00566)
 Observations                            69155         69155          69155        68928        68928        68928
 R2                                       0.063         0.318          0.328       0.129        0.399        0.412
 Quarter Fixed Effect                      Yes           No             No          Yes           No          No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                 No            Yes            Yes         No           Yes          Yes
 Weighted                                  No            No             No          Yes          Yes          Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of the growth quarterly bank level real estate backed lending
on bank leverage, CBSA house price growth and their interaction. Leverage is the ratio of tangible assets to tangible
equity. In first panel, I use an indicator for whether leverage is above the median for the CBSA-quarter. The second
panel uses leverage in its continuous form, winsorized at the 5% level. Columns 1 & 4 include quarter fixed effects,
while Columns 2,3,5 & 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed effects. Columns 1-3 are unweighted, while columns 4-6 weight
by the size of the bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the previous quarter. The sample runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes
bank holding companies which hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA or county, dropping observations in the
highest or lowest percentile of lending growth. The weighted regressions additionally drop banks 5 standard deviations
above the mean in commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered by CBSA/county.




                                                              35
                  Table 1.12: Housing Declines and Construction Lending: By Leverage

                                   (1)                (2)           (3)          (4)          (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for High Leverage
 High Leverage                  -0.0110∗∗          -0.0109∗∗     -0.00842∗∗   -0.00596∗    -0.00809∗∗    -0.0115∗∗
                                (0.00192)          (0.00223)      (0.00237)   (0.00238)     (0.00290)    (0.00242)

 House P rice Growth                    0.303∗∗                                 0.169∗∗
                                       (0.0366)                                (0.0370)

 High Leverage ×                       0.0857∗      0.0871∗       0.0818+      0.0616+      0.0782∗      0.0714∗
 House P rice Growth                   (0.0364)     (0.0430)      (0.0438)     (0.0354)     (0.0319)     (0.0311)
 Observations                           53435        53435         53435        53182        53182        53182
 R2                                     0.023         0.300         0.301       0.127         0.377       0.380

 Panel 2: Leverage
 Leverage                             -0.00360∗∗   -0.00286∗∗    -0.00220∗∗   -0.00215∗∗   -0.00240∗    -0.00354∗∗
                                      (0.000477)   (0.000605)    (0.000670)   (0.000749)   (0.00119)     (0.00108)

 House P rice Growth                   -0.0268                                  0.122
                                       (0.101)                                 (0.104)

 Leverage ×                            0.0354∗∗    0.0309∗∗      0.0295∗∗      0.00792      0.0154+       0.0136+
 House P rice Growth                  (0.00914)    (0.0106)      (0.0108)      (0.0101)    (0.00888)     (0.00784)
 Observations                           63374       63374         63374         63118        63118         63118
 R2                                      0.024       0.347         0.348        0.121        0.405         0.408
 Quarter Fixed Effect                     Yes         No            No           Yes           No            No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                No          Yes           Yes           No          Yes           Yes
 Weighted                                 No          No            No           Yes          Yes           Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of the growth quarterly bank level construction and land
development lending on bank leverage, CBSA house price growth and their interaction. Leverage is the ratio of
tangible assets to tangible equity. In first panel, I use an indicator for whether leverage is above the median for
the CBSA-quarter. The second panel uses leverage in its continuous form, winsorized at the 5% level. Columns
1 & 4 include quarter fixed effects, while Columns 2,3,5 & 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed effects. Columns 1-3 are
unweighted, while columns 4-6 weight by the size of the bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the previous quarter. The sample
runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes bank holding companies which hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA
or county, dropping observations in the highest or lowest percentile of lending growth. The weighted regressions
additionally drop banks 5 standard deviations above the mean in commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered
by CBSA/county.




                                                            36
                       Table 1.13: Housing Declines and CRE Lending: By Leverage

                                   (1)                (2)           (3)          (4)           (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: Indicator for High Leverage
 High Leverage                  0.000342           0.000318      -0.000761    0.000187     0.0000452     -0.000235
                               (0.000913)          (0.00104)     (0.00105)    (0.00115)    (0.00128)     (0.00121)

 House P rice Growth                    -0.0226                                 0.0210
                                       (0.0189)                                (0.0152)

 High Leverage ×                      0.0539∗∗     0.0566∗∗       0.0514∗      0.0418∗      0.0492∗       0.0412∗
 House P rice Growth                  (0.0189)     (0.0214)       (0.0208)     (0.0169)     (0.0197)      (0.0184)
 Observations                          57671        57671          57671        57321        57321         57321
 R2                                     0.010        0.233         0.236        0.033         0.288        0.291

 Panel 2: Leverage
 Leverage                              -0.000114    -0.000185    -0.000647∗   -0.000644∗    -0.000373     -0.000555
                                      (0.000206)   (0.000293)    (0.000293)   (0.000324)   (0.000394)    (0.000374)

 House P rice Growth                   -0.159∗∗                                 -0.0519
                                       (0.0425)                                (0.0562)

 Leverage ×                            0.0158∗∗     0.0153∗∗      0.0136∗∗    0.00875+      0.0130∗∗      0.0108∗
 House P rice Growth                  (0.00355)    (0.00512)     (0.00498)    (0.00456)    (0.00462)     (0.00449)
 Observations                           68219        68219         68219        67855        67855         67855
 R2                                      0.010        0.275         0.278       0.032         0.329        0.332
 Quarter Fixed Effect                     Yes          No            No          Yes           No           No
 CBSA-Quarter Fixed Effect                No           Yes           Yes         No            Yes          Yes
 Weighted                                 No           No            No          Yes           Yes          Yes
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of the growth quarterly bank level non-farm non-residential
real estate backed lending on bank leverage, CBSA house price growth and their interaction. Leverage is the ratio
of tangible assets to tangible equity. In first panel, I use an indicator for whether leverage is above the median for
the CBSA-quarter. The second panel uses leverage in its continuous form, winsorized at the 5% level. Columns
1 & 4 include quarter fixed effects, while Columns 2,3,5 & 6 include CBSA-quarter fixed effects. Columns 1-3 are
unweighted, while columns 4-6 weight by the size of the bank’s C&I loan portfolio in the previous quarter. The sample
runs from 2007 to 2010 and includes bank holding companies which hold over 50% of their deposits in one CBSA
or county, dropping observations in the highest or lowest percentile of lending growth. The weighted regressions
additionally drop banks 5 standard deviations above the mean in commercial lending. Standard errors are clustered
by CBSA/county.




                                                            37
Chapter 2


Housing Bust, Bank Lending &

Employment: Evidence From

Multimarket Banks

2.1      Introduction

Prior to the financial crisis of 2008, house prices in the US dropped precipitously. During the ensuing

recession, employment dropped by over 8.5 million as banks drastically tightened lending standards.1

By the time real GDP per capita rebounded to its previous peak at the end of 2013, over 500 banks

had failed. This economic turmoil was predominantly concentrated in the regions that experienced

the greatest decline in house prices, raising the question of how real estate declines impacted the

supply of credit and the general economy.

   The previous chapter established that banks which were exposed to falling house prices contracted

the supply of commercial credit. Given prior work demonstrating that contractions in the availability

of credit can impact labor markets (Ashcraft, 2005; Chodorow-Reich, 2014), this suggests that a

contraction in bank lending may have contributed to the strong relationship between real estate

declines and employment growth during the Great Recession. This chapter quantifies the effect that

declining bank health due to falling house prices had on employment during this period.
   1 The Survey of Terms of Business Lending reports that the quarterly spread on commercial and industrial loans

over the intended federal funds rate varied between 3.05 and 3.49 in the two years following the failure of Lehman
Brothers. It had never previously exceeded 2.67 since the survey began in 1986. Banks responding to the Senior Loan
Officer Opinion Survey also reported an unprecedented tightening of lending standards during the recession (Bassett
et al., 2014).


                                                        38
    The primary difficultly in isolating this effect is that falling house prices can impact the economy

through numerous other channels. One leading explanation is that declining house prices reduce

household wealth and the ability to borrow against home equity, thus reducing aggregate demand

and employment (Midrigan and Philippon, 2011; Mian et al., 2013; Mian and Sufi, 2014; Eggertsson

and Krugman, 2012; Guerrieri and Lorenzoni, 2015). Other explanations include real estate declines

impairing business collateral or prompting a sectoral shift out of construction.2

    I disentangle the quantitative significance of the bank lending channel from these other channels

using variation in the exposure of multimarket banks to real estate declines in other counties. While

each theory predicts that declining house prices within a county will result in falling lending and

employment, they differ in predictions regarding the impact of declines elsewhere along the branch

network of locally operating banks. If adverse shocks matter through bank losses, then borrowers

located in strong real estate markets will still face a contraction in credit if their bank is exposed

to real estate declines elsewhere. On the other hand, if real estate shocks predominantly impact

demand, then outside declines should induce a substitution of credit towards local borrowers and

not be associated with adverse outcomes.

    In short, I ask whether it was falling house prices locally which impacted the economy, or whether

it was instead the overall exposure of local banks to housing declines. This approach is enabled by

three characteristics of the banking sector. First, most bank lending is done by large multimarket

banks. Thus, the health of a typical borrower’s bank depends largely on conditions in other counties

where the bank has branches. Second, most small business lending is highly local. Thus, a reduction

in the supply of credit from a bank will predominantly affect counties in which the bank operates,

especially within a small window around its branches. Finally, asymmetric information problems

make switching banks costly. Consequently, the incidence of a shock to a bank will largely fall on

the bank’s existing customers instead of on the aggregate supply of credit. Taken together, these

characteristics imply that the availability of credit in a particular area will be impacted by conditions

in different and often distant markets where the nearby banks have other branches.

    First, I demonstrate that banks which were exposed to falling house prices contracted credit.

Using county level small business lending data from the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA), I

estimate lending growth as a function of a bank’s exposure to falling house prices, and county controls

or fixed effects. A one standard deviation decline in bank health, i.e. a greater average decline in

housing wealth where the bank has branches, results in a 13.4% reduction in county originations of
   2 See Chaney et al. (2012); Fairlie and Krashinsky (2012); Adelino et al. (2013); Fort et al. (2013); Mehrotra and

Sergeyev (2014) for evidence of the collateral channel and Hadi (2011); Rognlie et al. (2014); Hoffmann and Lemieux
(2014) for evidence of the construction channel.


                                                         39
small business loans. The magnitude of this estimate increases slightly when real estate controls

or county fixed effects are included. Banks which are exposed to real estate declines uniformly cut

lending throughout their network, not in the actual counties experiencing falling house prices. This

is consistent with real estate declines impacting the supply of credit instead of demand.

   Second, and most importantly, I show that this contraction in lending caused a decline in em-

ployment. A one standard deviation increase in the exposure of local banks to negative housing

wealth shocks, controlling for the shock in the county, decreases total employment by 1.2% between

2007 and 2010. Although changes in housing wealth do directly relate to employment growth, bank

exposure is found to a more important driver of employment declines.

   Given that bank health impacts the availability of mortgage credit (Berrospide et al., 2013) and

mortgage credit impacts house price growth (Loutskina and Strahan, 2015), falling house prices

locally might be a consequence of bank distress. This would make controlling for the local growth in

house prices overly conservative. To overcome this, I next use an alternative method to separate the

bank lending channel from the direct effects of house price declines which doesn’t require the use of

the endogenous control. Specifically, I instrument for the health of local banks using only exposure

to real estate declines in other markets. When I instrument for bank health using the exposure of

locally operating banks to real estate shocks in different CBSAs, I find that a one standard deviation

decline in bank health reduces employment by 2%.3 Similar results are found when instrumenting

for bank health using only the exposure to shocks in geographically distant counties.

   The IV estimate of the effect of bank health on employment growth is virtually identical to the

corresponding OLS estimate: a 2.0% employment response to the one standard deviation shock

for IV vs. 2.1% for OLS. Thus the relationship between bank health and employment growth is

not driven by local house price movements. Instead, it is the total multimarket exposure of the

local banks which relates to employment growth, with falling house prices elsewhere along the

branch network having a virtually symmetric effect on employment growth as declines in the actual

county. Furthermore, the relationship between bank health and employment growth is not driven

by spillovers from neighboring counties, as declines in geographically distant counties or in other

CBSAs also impact local employment growth. This is consistent with an adverse shock to a bank

in one area propagating through the bank’s internal capital market and uniformly impacting the

availability of credit anywhere the bank operates.

   Finally, I use two sources of within county variation to provide further support for the proposed

mechanism. First, employment losses are concentrated in firms most reliant on bank finance. Some
  3A   CBSA contains an urban center of at least 10,000 people and adjacent areas with strong commuting ties.


                                                       40
industries are more prone to rely on external finance for technological reasons reflecting, for example,

the degree of economies of scale or length of product gestation periods (Rajan and Zingales, 1998). I

show that employment growth in industries with a high dependence on external finance is over 50%

more sensitive to local bank health. Similarly, as young firms have had little opportunity to retain

earnings and have minimal access to direct finance, they tend to rely more on bank lending (Black

and Strahan, 2002; Cetorelli and Strahan, 2006; Robb and Robinson, 2012). I show that firms under

six years old are over twice as sensitive to bank health as mature firms.

    Second, employment losses disproportionately occur in tracts close to unhealthy banks. Since

small business lending is highly local and switching lenders is costly, differential shocks to the health

of local banks creates fine spatial variation in the availability of credit. A one standard deviation

decline in the health of the banks within 3km of a tract decreases employment by 1.7% relative to

other tracts in the county. As the county fixed effect should account for local demand or any other

county level confounder, this provides strong evidence that bank losses from real estate declines

result in a contraction in bank lending and harm to the general economy.

    Overall, my findings suggest that these effects are economically large. Even conservative esti-

mates have declining bank health from exposure to real estate shocks explaining roughly half of the

relationship between housing net worth shocks and employment declines, and 39% of the decline in

employment from 2007 to 2010.


2.1.1      Relation to Previous Literature

This paper contributes to several strands of the macroeconomics and finance literature. I add to

a vast literature identifying the degree to which shocks to the supply of bank credit impact the

economy.4 Additionally, I contribute to work studying the transmission of shocks through the

internal capital markets of geographically dispersed banks.5 This paper also complements work on

the roles of relationships and distance in the provision of bank credit, as the highly localized effects

I find require either high switching costs or difficulty obtaining a loan from distant banks.6

    First and foremost, this paper fits into the literature studying the effect of credit market frictions

on employment in the Great Recession. Existing work provides mixed evidence regarding the channel
   4 Gertler and Gilchrist (1994); Peek et al. (2003); Ashcraft (2005); Bassett et al. (2014) find that bank credit supply

shocks impact employment or investment, Driscoll (2004); Ashcraft (2006); Jim´      enez et al. (2014) on the other hand
find no real effects.
   5 Peek and Rosengren (2000); Chava and Purnanandam (2011); Cetorelli and Goldberg (2012) for example study

spillovers through multinational banks, while Morgan et al. (2004); Huang and Stephens (2011); Berrospide et al.
(2013); Bord et al. (2014) focus on the United States.
   6 Slovin et al. (1993); Khwaja and Mian (2008); Chodorow-Reich (2014) demonstrate adverse outcomes for clients

of banks who experienced a negative shock. Kwast et al. (1997); Petersen and Rajan (2002); Brevoort and Hannan
(2006); Brevoort and Wolken (2009) find that small businesses rely on nearby banks.


                                                           41
emphasized in this paper. Chodorow-Reich (2014) finds that a contraction in bank lending can

explain roughly 40% of the decline in employment in small and medium sized firms in the year

following Lehman’s bankruptcy. However, Greenstone et al. (2014) find that the contraction in small

business lending explains less than 3% of the decline in small business employment. Regarding the

role of falling house prices, Huang and Stephens (2011); Bord et al. (2014) find that banks exposed

to real estate declines reduced small business lending. On the other hand, Mian and Sufi (2014)

find that the employment losses in counties with falling house prices were attributable to falling

aggregate demand instead of credit supply. As my paper relates closely to each of these studies, I

will briefly describe each one in turn.7

    My approaches to identifying supply shocks closely follows Huang and Stephens (2011) and

Bord et al. (2014). They similarly create bank level measures of exposure to real estate declines, and

demonstrate that highly exposed banks cut small business lending relative to other banks operating in

the same area. My primary contribution is to assess how the supply contraction impacts employment.

As these papers largely rely on area fixed effects to account for local loan demand, they have more

to say about the composition of which banks lend in the county than on aggregate impacts.

    The findings of this paper are most similar to Chodorow-Reich (2014). He finds that the large

contraction in syndicated lending documented by Ivashina and Scharfstein (2010) translates into

employment declines in firms with a prior relationship to banks which contracted credit. He takes

advantage of impressive data on firm-lender relationships to document that banking relationships are

sticky and that shocks to banks impact their customers. However, he acknowledges two difficulties

in the identification of aggregate effects. First, there is a concern about external validity. The credit

contraction only significantly influenced employment in firms with fewer than 1000 employees, a

category severely underrepresented in the syndicated loan data.8 If the rare small firm borrowing in

the syndicated loan market is more financially dependent than the norm, the aggregate employment

effects could be overstated. Second, employment losses at the firm level are difficult to relate to

losses in aggregate without precise knowledge of the extent of general equilibrium effects. Wage or

price adjustments may influence the quantity of labor demanded by unconstrained firms and offset

much of the decline in employment due to a shock to a particular firm.
   7 This review is far from exhaustive. Additionally, Almeida et al. (2012) and Duchin et al. (2010) find evidence of

financial constraints among Compustat firms, while Kahle and Stulz (2013) does not. Campello et al. (2010) uses a
survey approach to identify real effects of financial constraints. Duygan-Bump et al. (2015) find that workers in small
firms and financially dependent industries were most likely to become unemployed. Goetz and Gozzi (2010) show
MSAs with banks relying on wholesale funding experienced larger employment declines.
   8 His data includes 798 large firms (1000+ employees) and 1242 small/medium firms (<1000 employees). Based

on the 2008 Business Dynamics Statistics, there were 10,839 large firms in the US versus 5.2 million small/medium
firms.




                                                          42
    Using county level data in my study lessens these concerns. The employment data includes

almost every firm in the county, and the bank data includes every bank or savings and loan with a

branch in the county, so external validity is no longer a problem. Additionally, using the county as

the unit of observation means that general equilibrium effects felt within the county are incorporated

into the aggregate effects. If a person is laid off by a constrained firm, but hired by another firm in

the same county, this would not appear as a decline in employment in my data.9

    The estimating equations in this paper closely follow Mian and Sufi (2014), who demonstrate

that non-tradable employment falls in counties experiencing adverse real estate shocks. They argue

that the lack of an employment response in tradable industries indicates that the employment losses

are due to low aggregate demand stemming from the loss in housing wealth. My empirical approach

separates the employment losses attributable to the decline in bank health from the direct effects

of local house price declines. I find that much of the decline in employment is due to differences in

bank exposure instead of directly due to local house price movements.

    I do find that bank exposure disproportionately impacts non-tradable employment, however this

can be reconciled with a credit supply shock in a couple ways. First, unhealthy banks may cut

consumer credit and thus reduce local aggregate demand. This is supported by Gropp et al. (2014),

who find that renters reduced their levels of debt in places with falling house prices, suggesting

that the decline in credit operated through channels besides household wealth. Second, the general

equilibrium effects of a shock to business credit would cause a shift of employment into tradable

industries. A credit contraction reduces the demand for labor (Benmelech et al., 2011), then falling

wages and employment decrease demand for local non-traded goods. In the appendix, I demonstrate

that a contraction in credit has an ambiguous effect on tradable employment due to wage adjust-

ments. In support of this explanation, I show in the robustness section that counties with exposed

banks experience declines in the cost of unskilled labor.

    Finally, Greenstone et al. (2014) investigate the role of small business lending in explaining the

contraction in employment. They identify shocks to the supply of small business lending using the

CRA data, and argue that the reduction in small business lending can only account for a small

fraction of the overall decline in employment.10 Like this paper, they test how the average health
    9 This does not completely address the concern about general equilibrium effects. Falling incomes locally will reduce

the demand for traded goods elsewhere, and rising prices of constrained firms would increase demand for competing
firms. However, these effects are likely less concerning than within county wage adjustments offsetting a reduction in
a firm’s employment.
   10 Specifically, they use the CRA data to estimate bank×county level loan growth using county and bank fixed

effects, taking the bank fixed effect to be a bank level supply shock. They instrument for small business lending with
the average supply shock of the banks operating in the county, and find that the elasticity of employment growth with
respect to lending is too small to have played a large role in the overall losses during the Great Recession.




                                                           43
of the banks in a county impact employment. However, they rely on a sample of large banks11 and

a narrow type of bank lending: loans to firms with less than $1 million in revenue which aren’t

backed by real estate. However, small banks disproportionately lend to small firms and are more

prone to rely on soft information in lending decisions (Berger and Udell, 2002; Berger et al., 2005).

As a result, this sample excludes many lending relationships, and particularly ones for which the

adverse selection problem in switching banks would be most severe. Furthermore, bank losses could

impact mortgage lending, other lending to individuals, commercial lending backed by real estate and

lending to larger firms, none of which are included in their data. My county level measure of bank

health incorporates the condition of every bank or savings and loan which locates within a county,

and more generally reflects the availability of credit for any type of lending which occurs through

bank branches. This broader scope may explain why I find much larger effects of bank distress than

Greenstone et al. (2014).

    The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 discusses

the empirical strategies. Section 4 presents the findings. Section 5 discusses robustness with regard

to alternative outcome variables, bank health measures and controls. Section 6 concludes.



2.2      Data Sources

2.2.1      Real Estate Shock Variables

I follow Mian and Sufi (2014) and measure real estate distress using the change in household net

worth due to house price movements. Their primary explanatory variable is:

                                                                              Hc,2006
                            ∆N etW orthc = ∆ln(HouseP rice)c,06−09
                                                                             N Wc,2006

    Where ∆ln(HouseP rice)c,06−09 is house price growth from Core Logic, Hc,2006 is housing wealth

and N Wc,2006 is the net worth of residents in the county.12

    This variable estimates the loss in home equity for residents of a county as a fraction of their

net worth. More leverage means a given decline in house prices has a larger wealth effect. However,

since the majority of household wealth is held in housing (Iacoviello, 2011), high leverage is also
  11 In their sample, 654 banks operate at some point from 1997-2010, with the number being smaller during the crisis

due to a change in reporting thresholds in 2005.
  12 Housing wealth is imputed from 2000 census data on the housing stock and subsequent house price growth, while

the net worth of residents is the sum of housing wealth and financial wealth less debt. Stock and bond holdings are
imputed based on IRS Statistics of Income data on stock and bond income combined with market returns. Debt data
come from Equifax. See Mian et al. (2013) for more details. This variable was downloaded from the replication files
available on the Econometrica website.



                                                         44
indicative of high loan to value ratios on the mortgages in the county. Consequently, banks in areas

where housing net worth declines steeply would experience greater loan losses.

   My measure of bank distress is based on the degree to which a bank locates in counties with

declining housing net worth. I use deposit and branch location data from the FDIC’s Summary

of Deposits (SOD) to determine a bank’s exposure to a particular county.13 A bank is deemed

unhealthy if it holds deposits in weak real estate markets.14 A county is deemed unhealthy if local

deposits are in unhealthy banks. Specifically:

                                                       X Db
                                                          c
                                   Bank Healthb =           ∆N etW orthc
                                                         Db
                                                       c∈C


                                                          X Db
                                                             c
                               Bank Health Cntyc =             Bank Healthb
                                                            Dc
                                                          b∈B


Where Dcb is the deposits held by bank b in county c and Db and Dc are the aggregate deposits

in the bank and the county respectively. Deposits are as of June 30th, 2006 for the main analysis,

although I additionally use bank health based on 2002 deposits as a robustness check. I additionally

try weighting by the value of 2006 mortgage originations and get similar results.

   For the tract level employment regressions, I additionally create a variable calculating the health

of the banks within a certain distance of a tract:


                                                          X
                           Bank Health T ractt (d) =            ωc,b (d)Bank Healthb
                                                          b∈B

where ωc,b (d) is the share of deposits within dkms of tract t’s centroid held in branches of b.15


2.2.2     Lending Growth

I use Community Reinvestment Act data for county level small business lending. This includes

business loan originations under $1 million in value originated by banks with over $1 billion in

assets in 2005 dollars. The variable of interest is growth in originations during the crisis (2008-2010)

relative to the pre-crisis period (2004-2006). I drop county×bank observations if the bank acquired

another bank in the same CBSA during the period of observation, if it is in the highest or lowest
  13 The SOD is an annual survey of branch offices for all FDIC-insured institutions, including commercial banks,

thrifts, and US branches of foreign banks.
  14 Banks which are part of a multibank holding company are aggregated to the level of the regulatory high holder.

Houston et al. (1997) shows that subsidiary loan growth depends more on the cash flows and capital of the holding
company than of the subsidiary, making the holding company the proper unit of analysis.
  15 I use the ARCGIS10 North American Address Locater to geocode the location for each bank branch in order to

calculate the distances to census tracts.



                                                        45
percentile of lending growth or if the bank didn’t have a branch within the county in 2006.


2.2.3      Labor Market Outcomes

County×industry employment data comes from the County Business Patterns (CBP). CBP provides

mid-march employment at the county level for NAICS industries constructed from the US Census

Bureau’s Business Register. I use the Mian and Sufi (2014) classification of 4-digit NAICS industries

as tradable or non-tradable.16 I follow Rajan and Zingales (1998) and measure financial dependence

based on the ability of firms in the industry to fund capital expenditures with cash flows. An

industry is classified as financially dependent if the median Compustat firm in the 3-digit industry

had capital expenditures exceeding cash flows from operations.17 Total employment for a given

category (e.g. non-tradable or financially dependent) is calculated by aggregating the employment

across the industries within a category.18 The dependent variable of interest is employment growth

from 2007 to 2010, either overall or for a particular set of industries.

    I use Quarterly Workforce Indicators (QWI) for data disaggregated by firm age or worker edu-

cation. QWI combines data from Unemployment Insurance matched with employer characteristics

from the Business Dynamic Statistics. The quarterly employment growth in a given age category is

the difference in the log of stable employment from the previous quarter.19 Growth from 2007 to

2010 is the sum of the quarterly growth rates from Q2 2007 to Q1 2010.20 Young firms are defined

as firms which are five years old or younger and mature firms are older than five.

    Additionally, I use QWI data on earnings and employment by education category to measure

wage growth. The wage for a particular type of worker (e.g. college educated workers) is the total

earnings of stable employees divided by the number of stable employees. I then calculate wage

growth from 2007 to 2010.21

    Tract employment comes from the Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics Origin-Destination

Employment Statistics (LODES) Workplace Area Characteristics. LODES provides employment at

the 2-digit NAICS level for 2010 census blocks, omitting Massachusetts and DC. Data are con-
  16 Restaurant and retail industries are classified as non-tradable, industries prominent in the world trade data are

classified as tradable.
  17 Cash flows and capital expenditures come from Compustat data on U.S. firms in the 1990s. This was used in

Coleman and Feler (2014). Thanks to Nick Coleman for sharing this with me.
  18 Some county×industry observations have data suppressed and instead provide a range containing the employment

value. Following Mian and Sufi (2014), I take the employment to be the midpoint of the range.
  19 Stable employment in a given quarter is the number of jobs where the employee was employed at the beginning

and end of the quarter.
  20 One cannot simply look at changes in employment by age group between 2007 and 2010 as firms will change age

categories in that period.
  21 People with low education disproportionately lost their jobs in areas with unhealthy banks. The increased

share of employment in highly educated people masks changes in average earnings in the county. Consequently, the
disaggregation by education type is needed to demonstrate how the cost of labor changed.


                                                         46
structed from state unemployment insurance records which are combined with Quarterly Census

of Employment and Wages data. I aggregate this to the 2010 census tract level. Growth is again

measured between 2007 and 2010.

   Table 1 presents summary statistics of the main variables of interest. The average county ex-

periences a decline in housing net worth of 9.5% from 2006 to 2009 with a standard deviation of

10%. The average decline in Bank Health Cnty is similar at 8.4%, but less variable with a standard

deviation of 4.2%. Banks in places with severely falling house prices tend to have other branches in

stronger markets, mitigating some of the damage from local real estate losses. However, there is still

far from perfect integration, creating cross county variation in the health of banks. Employment

dropped by 7.7% on average from March 2007 to March 2010.



2.3     Empirical Strategy

The goal of this paper is to demonstrate two things: First, banks which were exposed to real estate

declines contracted credit. Second, this credit contraction resulted in employment declines in areas

reliant on exposed banks.

   The primary difficulty is that bank exposure is likely correlated with other variables impacting

the demand for credit or demand for labor. In this section, I describe the empirical approaches to

control for these demand side effects. In the appendix, I present a simple model of bank credit and

employment to assist in the interpretation of the regression coefficients from the different approaches.


2.3.1       Impact of Real Estate Exposure on Small Business Lending

While the last chapter focused on smaller, predominantly single market banks, using cross sectional

differences across the banks locating in the same area, here I focus on larger multimarket banks. I

again separate supply from demand by comparing banks lending in the same area. However, now

I exploit geographic variation in the degree of exposure to house price declines elsewhere along the

bank’s branch network as in Huang and Stephens (2011) and Bord et al. (2014). I estimate the

equation:

                     ∆ln(SB Loans)b,c = β1 Bank Healthb + βx0 Xb,c + δc + b,c


The dependent variable is the growth in the number of small business loans the bank originated in

the county during the crisis (2008-20110) relative to before the crisis (2004-2006). As the county

fixed effect δc should account for demand, the coefficient on Bank Health should reflect the effect


                                                  47
that bank exposure to real estate declines has on the supply of credit. The hypothesis of this paper

is that banks which were exposed to real estate declines reduced lending, meaning that β1 > 0.

   The difference in the estimated effect of bank health in the fixed effect and simple regression

omitting δc will be informative as to the degree to which the relationship between bank health and

lending growth is driven by loan demand. If county lending growth has a supply and a demand

component: ∆ln(SB Loans)b,c = dc + sb + b,c , then the difference between the estimate in the fixed
                                         cov(Bank Health,dc )
effect and simple regression should be    var(Bank Health) .    If Bank Health reflects the supply of

credit, then the fixed effect and simple regression should be similar. If Bank Health mostly reflects

demand, then including the fixed effect should reduce the point estimate.

   Similarly I assess how the real estate shock variables impact the demand for loans by estimating:


        ∆ln(SB Loans)b,c = β1 Bank Health Cntyc + β2 ∆N etW orthc + βx0 Xb,c + δb + b,c


   The bank fixed effect δb accounts for bank level supply shocks, thus the coefficients reflect how

local real estate movements and changes in the health of local banks impact the demand for credit

from a particular bank. The hypothesis of this paper is that the health of the banks in the county

impacts the supply of credit. If this is true, we would expect β1 < 0. Namely, a contraction in

lending among other banks in the county would increase the demand for credit for a particular

bank, causing it to increase lending relative to other areas in which it operates. Conversely, if high

values of Bank Health Cnty reflected some omitted variable positively related to demand, then

individual banks should increase lending when competitors are measured as healthy, making β1 > 0.


2.3.2    Impact of Real Estate Exposure on Employment

Employment Approach 1: OLS, County Controls

The simplest approach to identifying the employment effect of bank losses from real estate exposure

is to estimate the equation:


             ∆ln(Emp)i,c = βB Bank Health Cntyc + βH ∆N etW orthc + βx0 Xc + i,c                (2.1)


Where ln(Emp)i,c is the employment for a given category i (total, non-tradable, or tradable), and

Xc is a set of variables giving the share of 2006 employment in each 2 digit NAICS industry.

   The assumption underlying this approach is that the control for ∆N etW orth adequately accounts

for direct demand side effects of declining house prices so that βB reflects the employment effects

                                                 48
of a credit contraction, instead of a direct effect of falling house prices. The bank lending channel

would predict that βB > 0, meaning that counties with healthier banks perform better than counties

with similar house price shocks, but local banks more exposed to other distressed counties.

    There are two major flaws in this strategy. First, real estate shocks are not exogenous. Falling

house prices could be a result of decreased mortgage lending from unhealthy banks, in which case

I would be over-controlling.22 Moreover, omitted variables impacting employment could correlate

with house price movements and bias the regression coefficients.23 For these reasons, the inclusion

of the control could bias βB downward. Second, the effects of low bank health could reflect spillovers

from declining wealth in other areas instead of declining lending. For example, people in adjoining

counties might reduce spending in local restaurants if they experience a negative wealth shock. This

could create an upward bias in βB . The next approach overcomes these concerns.


Employment Approach 2: Instrument with Exposure from Distant Markets

A similar strategy is to instrument for bank health using the exposure of local banks to house price

declines in other markets. This has two major benefits. First, this allows me to remove the effects of

own county house price declines without introducing an endogenous control. Thus the IV approach

without the control may fix a downward bias in the estimated coefficient on bank health in the OLS

specification including the control.

    Second, this approach reduces concerns about bank health reflecting spillovers from neighboring

counties. Falling house prices in other MSAs or hundreds of miles away are unlikely to directly affect

local demand as nearby declines would, thus any relationship between outside bank exposure and

local non-tradable employment can more comfortably to attributed to the bank lending channel.

Thus, I run IV regressions:


                                                      Healthc + βx0 Xc + i,c
                   Second Stage: ∆ln(Emp)i,c = βB Bankd
                                                                                                               (2.2)
                                      Healthi,c = ρB Outside Shockc + ρ0x Xc + ui,c
                     First Stage: Bankd


The outside shock is the component of bank health coming from the exposure of local banks to real
  22 Loutskina and Strahan (2015) find that an expansion in mortgage lending due to exogenous changes in the ease

of GSE securitization results in greater house price growth and employment growth.
  23 Contrary to this, Mian and Sufi (2014) find larger estimated effects when they instrument for changes in housing

net worth with the Saiz (2010) measure of the housing supply elasticity. However, the elasticity measure is highly
spatially correlated and only available at the MSA level. As a result, the instrument actually better correlates with
Bank Health Cnty than ∆N etW orth. This may contribute to why Mian and Sufi (2014) find larger point estimates
in their IV specifications.




                                                         49
estate shocks in other markets:

                                          X       X          Dcb Dcb0
                      Outside Shockc =                                ∆N etW orthc0
                                                             Dc Db
                                          b∈B c0 ∈{C\m(c)}



where m(c) denotes the set of counties in the same market as c. I define the market as the county,

the 2010 Core Based Statistical Area/rural county (CBSA) or the set of counties within a certain

distance of c.

   If the coefficient on bank health merely reflects spillovers from neighboring counties, then exclud-

ing variation from nearby counties should remove the effect of bank health. If real estate declines

matter though changes in bank equity, then it doesn’t matter whether the bank is exposed to de-

clines locally or in distant branches as the effect on the aggregate effect on the bank balance sheet

would be symmetric. In the extreme case with no direct demand effects, the OLS and IV estimates

should be the same.


Employment Approach 3: Difference in Differences by Bank Dependence

Once it is established that declining bank health results in employment losses, a natural follow-up

question is to what extent are the employment losses due to a contraction in commercial credit

versus consumer credit. One way to assess the role of declining business credit, is to test whether

bank dependent firms reduce employment more in areas with unhealthy banks.

   I use two definitions of bank dependence. First, I use the industry based classification of Rajan

and Zingales (1998). They measure financial dependence based on the cash flows and capital ex-

penditures of the firms in the industries. Being in an industry in which the majority of the firms

were unable to finance their capital expenditure with cash flows is taken to be an indicator of a

technological reliance on external finance.

   Second, I use an age based classification. Young firms have had little time to accumulate and

retain earnings. They also generally lack the transparency or size to make direct finance feasible.

As a result they are more reliant on banks than mature firms.

   I estimate equations as in the previous two sections and compare the coefficient for employment

growth in the high dependence and low dependence category. If the relationship between growth and

bank health solely reflects omitted demand related variables or a decline in consumer credit, there

would be little reason for them to impact financially dependent firms or young firms more. However,

as these firms are more reliant on banks, a greater sensitivity of employment to bank health would

support the claim that declining commercial credit contributed to the employment losses.

                                                  50
Employment Approach 4: Tract Growth, County Fixed Effects

Lastly, I exploit within county variation in proximity to exposed banks. A wide range of studies have

demonstrated that small business lending disproportionately occurs within a couple miles of a bank’s

branches (Kwast et al., 1997; Petersen and Rajan, 2002; Brevoort and Hannan, 2006; Brevoort and

Wolken, 2009). These findings are replicated in Figure 1, which plots the distribution of distances

between small businesses and their lender using data from the Survey of Small Business Finance

and Community Reinvestment Act.

    If either switching lenders is costly as in Sharpe (1990) or Chodorow-Reich (2014), or the reliance

on local banks reflects a spatial friction in lending as in Degryse and Ongena (2005) or Agarwal and

Hauswald (2010), then this would mean that an adverse shock to local banks would impact nearby

firms. In the first case, the localized nature of banking is a pure equilibrium outcome, but proximity

proxies for relationships. A shock to a bank would impact it’s existing customers due to the adverse

selection problem in switching lenders, and would thus disproportionately impact the firms near

their branches as they are most likely to have a relationship with that bank. In the second case,

distant firms are a poor substitute for near firms due to an actual advantage of proximity. For

example, if there is location specific soft information, only local lenders may be willing to make a

particular loan. If these lenders are contracting credit, it would be difficult to obtain a loan even

for new firms without an existing relationship. Either way, this spatial variation in the ability of

local banks to lend generates within county variation in the availability of credit. This allows me to

estimate:

                       ∆ln(Emp)t,c = βB Bank Health T ractt (d) + βx0 Xt + δc + t


where t indexes census tracts, Bank Health T ract(d) is the average health of the branches within

dkms of t, δc is a county fixed effect and Xt is a set of variables giving employment shares by 2-digit

NAICS industries. By comparing growth in tracts within the same county, I can remove any county

level demand effects and be more confident that the findings are due to a contraction in bank credit.

    Additionally I include an interaction with an indicator for whether the tract disproportionately

has employment in small establishments (establishments with fewer than 100 workers).24 Although

establishment size is an imperfect measure of financial dependence, having small establishments is a

necessary condition for having small firms. As such, these tracts should have an increased sensitivity
  24 Zip Code Business Patterns provides counts of establishments by size bin and industry. I can thus estimate the

amount of employment in small establishments and large establishments at the zip code × 2-digit industry level using
the midpoint of the size range. I then allocate this to the tract level using the 2006 two digit block level employment
data from LODES as a cross-walk between zip codes and census tracts.




                                                          51
to the health of nearby banks.



2.4     Findings

2.4.1    Exposed Banks Cut Small Business Lending

Table 2 estimates the impact of Bank Health on county level small business lending growth. A

10% shock to a bank causes it to reduce small business loan originations by 19%. When controls for

county shocks to net worth or county fixed effects are included, the predicted effect increases to 21%

or 22%. If real estate shocks impacted the demand for loans, then the reduction in lending would be

concentrated in the actual counties experiencing the shock. The fact that exposed banks uniformly

cut lending throughout their branch network indicates that real estate shocks predominantly impact

the supply of credit.

   That controlling for demand has such a minimal effect on the relationship between Bank Health

and lending may seem anomalous, but specifications (5) and (6) provide an explanation of what is

happening. The inclusion of bank fixed effects account for credit supply shocks, allowing one to

observe how county level variables influence loan demand. Counties with declining net worth see

demand increase, albeit insignificantly. However, once the average health of the banks in the county

are accounted for, the coefficient on ∆N etW orth switches signs. Banks cut lending where house

prices fall, but they allocate significantly more credit to places where the other banks are unhealthy.

A 10% decline in the health of the banks in the county, controlling for ∆N etW orth, results in an

11% increase in loan originations relative to other markets the bank lends in. This suggests that

demand doesn’t fall in places with declining net worth because of a contraction in the supply of

credit of competitors.

   This last point merits elaboration as it will support the findings in the employment section.

Conditional on ∆N etW orth, banks increase lending in counties with unhealthy banks, indicating an

elevated return to lending. This increase in demand could be due to a contraction in the supply of

loans from competing banks, or an increase in the overall demand for credit among small businesses.

Given that firms in these counties are laying off workers, and exposed banks are cutting lending, it

is unlikely that overall demand is rising. Consequently, this finding substantiates the claim that the

exposure of local banks to real estate declines adversely impacts the supply of bank credit.




                                                  52
2.4.2    Bank Exposure Causes Employment Declines

Having now informally established the “first stage” whereby the health of locally operating banks

impacts the supply of credit (conditional on county real estate conditions), the remainder of this

paper will be devoted to determining the labor market effects of this decline in bank health.


Employment Approach 1: OLS, County Controls

Table 3 directly estimates the relationship between employment growth and the real estate shock

variables as in equation 1. Adverse shocks to the net worth of households and to the health of

local banks are associated with declines in total employment and employment in the non-tradable

sector. When the variables of interest are included separately, a one standard deviation decline

in Bank Health Cnty (.042) reduces total employment by 2.1% and non-tradable employment by

2.7%. A one standard deviation decline in ∆N etW orth (.1) reduces overall employment by 2% and

non-tradable employment by 2.1%.

   The more informative regressions are those in columns (3) and (6), which include both variables.

A one standard deviation decrease in Bank Health Cnty, controlling for ∆N etW orth, reduces

employment by 1.2% and non-tradable employment by 2.7%. Bank Health Cnty remains significant

in both specifications.

   Combined with the finding of the previous section, we have that counties with exposed banks

(conditional on ∆N etW orth) see increased lending from large healthy banks but experience a con-

traction in employment. This indicates a high return to lending despite poor economic conditions,

consistent with a negative shock to the supply of bank credit.

   Tradable employment is not significantly related to either variable. As Mian and Sufi (2014)

note, the fact that I only find effects for non-tradable industries, i.e. industries reliant on local

demand, could be suggestive that employment declines are due to low aggregate demand. However,

as falling wages or employment from a credit disruption also would influence local demand, this

doesn’t rule out a shock to the supply of bank credity. In the robustness section, I present evidence

that the cost of labor fell in counties with unhealthy banks, a factor which could offset the effects

of a contraction in credit for tradable firms.


Employment Approach 2: Instrument with Exposure from Distant Markets

In Table 4, I instrument for Bank Health Cnty using only bank exposure to real estate declines in

different counties or CBSAs. Panel 1 presents the findings omitting the control for ∆N etW orth.


                                                 53
Interestingly, the estimated effects of a shock to bank health on overall or non-tradable employment

are virtually identical whether I instrument or not. The elasticity of employment growth with

respect to bank health only falls from .5 in the OLS specification to .47 in the IV specifications. For

non-tradable employment growth, the elasticity is .63 in the OLS specification and .62 or .66 in the

IV specifications. These results show that the relationship between bank health and employment

growth is not driven by falling house prices within the actual county, nor is it driven by falling house

prices in economically integrated areas. As individuals living in other MSAs account for a small

portion of the demand for local non-traded goods, this should increase confidence that the results

are actually driven by bank lending instead of aggregate demand.

   Accounting for direct effects of house price declines by excluding declines within the same market

may result in a better estimate than the previous approach. A contraction in the supply of bank

credit due to real estate losses would be likely to particularly impact mortgage availability, as banks

would be unwilling to take on additional real estate risk. This could make real estate declines in

part a consequence of poor bank health so that controlling for it would result in an understatement

the true effects. However, due to spatial correlation in house price movements and bank locations,

the outside exposure of local banks is likely to still be correlated ∆N etW orth for reasons beyond

the health of local banks impacting house prices.

   Panel 2 additionally controls for ∆N etW orth to address this concern. Again, point estimates

for the effects on overall and non-tradable employment are nearly identical in the OLS and the

two IV specifications. Instrumenting for Bank Health Cnty, causes the elasticity of employment

growth with respect to bank health decline from .28 in the OLS specification to .27 in both the

IV specification. For non-tradable employment growth, the estimates are .60 and .72 in the IV

specifications compared to .64 in the OLS specification. Bank Health Cnty is significant at the

5% or 10% level for overall employment growth and significant at the 1% level for non-tradable

employment growth, while ∆N etW orth remains insignificant. Both real estate shock variables

remain insignificant in the tradable employment specifications.

   Figure 2 presents a similar analysis using distance based market definitions. For each distance

up to 300kms, I calculate the component of bank health coming from counties more than that

distance from the county in question, and plot the coefficient on bank health in the employment

regression. In the total employment regressions, the estimate falls from .5 in the OLS specification

to .37 when instrumenting for bank health with exposure from counties over 300 km away. The

estimate when ∆N etW orth is controlled for drops from .28 to .18, although estimates quickly

become imprecise. Point estimates for non-tradable employment are remarkably stable. Without

                                                  54
the control, the estimated effect of bank health rises from .63 to .65, with the control it rises from

.64 to .68.

   Overall, this approach demonstrates that adverse shocks to banks have a roughly symmetric

effect on employment whether they occur locally or whether they occur in distant counties with

common banks. This is consistent with real estate declines causing a uniform contraction in lending

through out a bank’s branch network, but contrary to the demand channels where only local house

price declines should impact employment.


Employment Approach 3: Difference in Differences by Bank Dependence

Table 5 shows that these effects are magnified in firms in financially dependent industries. The

difference in the elasticity of growth with respect to bank health between highly and lowly dependent

industries is .23 in the IV regression using out of county exposure, .27 in the OLS specification, and

.33 with the outside CBSA instrument. Differences are significant at the 5% or 10% level. In the

OLS specification, a one standard deviation decline in bank health reduces employment by 1.6% in

low dependence industries but 2.8% in high dependence industries.

   In the second panel, I control for ∆N etW orth. Bank health is always significant for growth

in highly dependent industries. The difference in elasticities is still positive in every specification,

although it is no longer statistically significant. The estimated effect of local net worth shocks is

always small and statistically insignificant.

   A concern with the Rajan and Zingales (1998) definition of financial dependence is that it is

based on the financing needs of large Compustat firms. As a result, it may not be representative

of the financial dependence of the types of businesses which would rely on local banks. Another

approach is to test how the sensitivity varies by firm age.

   Table 6 shows that employment growth in young firms responds more to differences in bank

health. When omitting ∆N etW orth control, the difference in the elasticity between young firms

and mature firms varies between .43 and .67 and is always significant at at least the 5% level. In the

OLS specification, a one standard deviation decline in bank health is found to reduce employment

by 1.6% in mature firms and 3.6% in young firms. Additionally controlling for the own county shock

causes the difference in elasticities to shrink to .25 and .2 in the OLS and outside county specification,

and become insignificant. When instrumenting with outside CBSA exposure, the difference increases

to .85 and remains significant at the 5% level despite the larger standard errors.

   In short, the decline in employment occurred predominantly in the firms most likely to be im-

pacted by a contraction in commercial credit. As there is little reason to think that these firms

                                                   55
would be more sensitive to demand shocks, this provides evidence that the findings are largely not

driven by a decline in consumer credit or some other demand related variable.


Employment Approach 4: Tract Growth, County Fixed Effects

A decline in small business lending from a particular bank would also differentially affect firms based

on their location within the county. Since small business lending is very local, the firms within a

couple miles of the exposed banks should face the greatest employment declines. Table 7 shows that

having the banks within 3km of a tract be highly exposed to falling house prices results in lower

employment growth relative to other tracts in the same county. I find that a 10% shock to nearby

banks reduces employment growth by 3.9%.

   Exposure to unhealthy banks matters predominantly for tracts with more employment in small

establishments. A 10% shock reduces growth by 2.4% in tracts above the county median in the share

of employment in large establishments and 4.6% in tracts more reliant on small establishments. I

still find a significant impact on employment and a significantly larger effect on small establishments

when I do not weight by 2006 tract employment, although the point estimates are smaller.

   In the last four columns, I measure Bank Health T ract with an indicator for whether the banks

within 3kms are healthier than the county median. Tracts close to unhealthy banks experience

employment growth 1.4% lower than tracts near healthy banks. When I include the interaction for

whether the tract is reliant on small establishments, I find that tracts reliant on large establish-

ments, regardless of bank health, and tracts reliant on small establishments near healthy banks all

perform almost identically. However, tracts with small establishments and unhealthy banks expe-

rience growth which is 2.1% lower than the rest of the county. Omitting the employment weights

again results in qualitatively similar findings but lower magnitudes.

   Figure 3 shows how the finding depends on the distance used to define a tract’s banking market.

The left panel plots coefficients from regressions of tract employment growth on bank health and

county fixed effects. For each value d on the x-axis, bank health is measured as the deposit weighted

health of the branches within dkm of the tract. For distances from 2km to 16km, there is little

noticeable trend, with the coefficient on bank health being mostly around .3 or .4 and always

significantly different from 0.

   The right panel presents similar results, except using the discrete bank health measure, and

including the interaction for whether the tract is composed of small establishments. Each line shows

the predicted growth rate for a tract of a given health and size category relative to a tract with

large establishments near healthy banks. Here the distance parameter is more relevant. For low

                                                  56
values (2-7km) we see that tracts with healthy banks or large establishments mostly have similar

growth rates, with employment growth in tracts with small establishments and unhealthy banks

being about 2% lower. Larger distance parameters attenuate the predicted effect of bank health on

small establishment growth.

   Much like with the heterogeneous effects by bank dependence, this finding provides evidence

that a contraction in commercial credit from unhealthy banks resulted in employment losses. Two

firms in the same county are likely to face similar market wages, and similar levels of demand from

consumers. However, by virtue of banking markets being more local than labor or housing markets,

there would still be within county spatial variation in the availability of credit. The concentration of

employment losses in the firms most likely to borrow from unhealthy banks provides strong evidence

in favor of the bank lending channel.



2.5      Robustness and Extensions

2.5.1     Wage Adjustment

Most of the evidence in this paper supports the theory that real estate declines resulted in a contrac-

tion in bank commercial credit and, as a result, a decline in employment. The observed declines in

lending to small businesses, employment in bank dependent firms, and employment in firms near un-

healthy banks would all be explained by this theory. However, the greater sensitivity of employment

in non-tradable industries may be taken as evidence of a demand channel.25

   The minimal relationship between tradable employment and bank health can however be rec-

onciled with a credit supply shock if falling wages offset the effects of tighter credit conditions for

tradable firms. If a contraction in credit lowers labor demand, this would result in a reductions in

wages and employment. This decline in local income would in turn reduce the demand for firms

in local non-tradable industries. The impact on tradable employment would thus depend on the

strength of wage adjustments. With an inelastic labor supply and flexible wages, tradable employ-

ment would rise as workers move into the industries with relatively higher demand. With perfectly

rigid wages, tradable employment falls due to the contraction in credit. With imperfect adjustment,

the falling wages and credit availability could offset, leaving employment unchanged. Under this

chain of events, non-tradable employment does fall due to low local demand, but that low demand

is a consequence of falling labor demand instead of the cause.
  25 Note that this demand channel needn’t be the housing wealth channel. Bank deleveraging could cause a reduction

in consumer credit resulting in a contraction in demand. This would explain why bank health matters beyond local
real estate declines.


                                                        57
    For this to be a credible explanation however, I need to demonstrate that wages fell in places

with unhealthy banks. Mian and Sufi (2014) address this issue, demonstrating that the average wage

growth largely did not respond to changes in the net worth of households.26 Their wage measure, the

average payroll of the workers in the county, might not accurately reflect the cost of labor though.

If temporary or low skilled workers have lower search or training costs, they could be more readily

laid-off. Wage declines could then be masked by a change in the composition of the workforce to

include a higher percentage of high wage individuals.

    To mitigate this issue, I use the QWI earnings data disaggregated by education category. Table

8 provides evidence that places with unhealthy banks did indeed have declining labor costs. The

first panel estimates the impact of bank health on changes in average earnings from 2007 to 2010.

Specification (1) shows that the average wage overall doesn’t significantly respond to bank health,

with a 10% shock to bank health only reducing wages by 1.6%. However, specifications (2)-(4) show

that a 10% shock reduces the cost of young workers (under 25 years) by 3.8%, workers without a

high school diploma by 2.9%, and workers with no college by 2.3%. All are significant at the 1 or

5% level. Workers with a college education see a modest and insignificant decline in wages, similar

in magnitude to the average decline in wages in (1).27

    The second panel shows that declining bank health disproportionately results in employment

losses for workers under 25 and workers who did not complete high school. As these individuals

have the lowest wages, their job losses obscure the actual changes in the cost of labor as observed

using overly aggregated data. Given that education is an imperfect proxy for skill, it is likely that this

disaggregation by education bin doesn’t entirely fix the composition bias. Any worker with higher

match specific human capital is likely to generate surplus for both the employer and employee,

making the job higher paying than for similarly educated people, and making the employee less

likely to lose their job.


2.5.2      Instrumenting with Earlier Branch Locations

While most of this paper focuses on ruling out demand side explanations, another threat is that bank

locations are not exogenous. A bank may have a high exposure to real estate declines not because

of historical accident, but because it specifically chose to enter markets with certain characteristics.

Thus a relationship between unhealthy banks and unemployment declines could reflect an omitted
  26 Other work on the wage rigidities during the Great Recession using national data have found mixed results. Daly

et al. (2012) presents evidence of downward nominal rigidity in wages. Elsby et al. (2013) argues that this rigidity
may be less binding than typically hypothesized.
  27 These findings should be taken as weaker than the employment findings, as including the control for ∆N etW orth

makes both variables insignificant.


                                                        58
variable which induced particular banks (subprime specialists for example) to enter the market.

    To overcome this concern, I test the robustness of my main findings to using 2002 branch locations

to compute the bank health measures. As the spike in subprime mortgage originations and private

label securitization occurred in 2004, there should be less concern about locations in 2002 reflecting

unobserved variables relating to the housing boom. In Tables 9 and 10, I replicate the primary

county level and tract level findings instrumenting for the bank health measures using analogous

measures constructed from 2002 branch locations and deposit levels, instead of the 2006 ones as in

the main paper. The results are virtually identical to the equivalent specifications in Tables 3 and

7, alleviating concerns about endogenous location decisions in response to the housing boom driving

my results.


2.5.3      Alternative Bank Health Measures

There are numerous potential measures of county real estate distress or ways of measuring a bank’s

exposure to a given county. The first six tables of the supplementary materials show that the

primary findings are not sensitive to my measure of bank health. In addition to ∆N etW orthc , I

also measure county real estate health as (1 − Delinquencyc ), where Delinquencyc is the December

2009 delinquency rate on mortgages in county c from the New York Fed Consumer Credit Panel

(a 5% sample of US consumers with a credit report). I additionally measure a bank’s exposure

to a county based on the value of mortgage originations for home purchases in 2006, using Home

Mortgage Disclosure Act county lending data. This has the benefit of picking up exposure from

mortgages originated by non-depository affiliates of bank holding companies or other mortgage

lending in counties where the bank doesn’t have branches.28 Combinations of these two exposure

measures with the two county shocks provide four potential bank health measures.

    Which measure of bank health appears to matter relatively little on average. Using one of

the three new measures tends to strengthen the out of market IV findings and external financial

dependence findings, but weakens the findings by age and at the tract level. However, using a

different measure of bank health never changes the qualitative predictions.


2.5.4      Alternative Controls

Tables 7-9 in the supplemental materials also present robustness for four different control sets. I

either include nothing besides the variables of interest, 2-digit industry shares as in the paper,
  28 Since small banks and banks outside of MSAs are exempt from filing, I limit the sample to MSAs in the employment

regressions.


                                                         59
industry shares along with the demographic controls used in Mian and Sufi (2014)29 , or the industry

controls with state fixed effects. Overall, the estimates provided in the paper tend to be on the

lower end, although qualitatively similar to the findings with the alternative control sets. The

largest difference occurs when state fixed effects are used. The state fixed effects strengthen the

findings based on external financial dependence. However, their inclusion makes ∆N etW orth and

Bank Health Cnty insignificant for young and mature firms alike.



2.6      Conclusion

Determining the reason that falling house values translated into employment declines is difficult

due to the similarity in the aggregate implications of different channels. Both declining aggregate

demand and loan supply would result in falling consumption, lending and employment.

   Yet despite the near observational equivalence of the channels, the policy prescriptions can vary

substantially. Proponents of the demand view might favor empowering bankruptcy judges to reduce

the amount of principle owed on a mortgage, a provision of the Helping Families Save Their Homes

Act of 2009 which was dropped in the senate. Those believing the banking channel would advocate

for the liquidity support and capital injections as were undertaken by government during the height

of the crisis. Forced principle reductions here could be counterproductive if they caused further

losses to banks in areas with depressed real estate values. These starkly different policy implications

of similarly plausible channels has resulted in a contentious debate regarding the policy response to

the crisis.

   In this paper, I demonstrate that losses in the banking system contributed to the decline in

lending and employment between 2007 to 2010. Counties with exposed banks saw increases in

lending from large healthy banks, but falling employment. This set of outcomes is consistent with a

contraction in credit in these counties, but is hard to reconcile with demand based narratives. The

disproportionate employment declines in young firms, financially dependent firms and firms close to

unhealthy banks lends further credence to the banking view.

   A back of the envelope calculation indicates that the employment declines due to this contraction

in bank lending were substantial. The less conservative approach in estimating the aggregate effect

of these bank losses is to assume that county housing net worth declines are endogenous and thus

controlling for them causes a downward bias on the coefficient for bank health. Instrumenting for
  29 This includes: percentage white, median household income, percentage owner-occupied, percentage with less than

a high school diploma, percentage with only a high school diploma, unemployment rate, poverty rate, and percentage
urban.



                                                        60
bank health with real estate movements in counties over 300km away produces an estimated elasticity

of employment growth with respect to bank health of .37. If one is more concerned about spatial

correlation in house prices than their endogeneity, the specification controlling for ∆N etW orth

would be appropriate, generating a coefficient of .28. The average population weighted decline in

county level bank health was .085, thus these estimates imply that declining bank health from real

estate exposure reduced employment by between 2.4% and 3%. US employment at the beginning

of the sample in March 2007 was 137.72 million, thus this amounts to a loss of between 3.3 and 4.1

millions jobs accounting for between 39% and 48% of the aggregate decline in employment.

    In addition to the bank lending channel being significant in aggregate, it also goes a long way

in explaining why employment fell in places with falling house prices. Controlling for bank health

causes the coefficient on ∆N etW orth to fall from .2 to .11, thus bank health also explains almost

half of the relationship between shocks to the net worth of households and employment.30 I am

by no means dismissing the existence of a direct effect of housing declines on employment, or the

efficacy of policies to assist homeowners during the crisis. However, my analysis demonstrates that

those direct effects are not the entire story. The ability of banks to lend was a significant driver of

labor market strength in the Great Recession, and played a large part in explaining why employment

declines were so pronounced in places with falling house prices. This all suggests that the dramatic

actions by the Fed and the Treasury to rehabilitate the financial system after the failure of Lehman

Brothers was vitally important in preventing the crisis from being worse than it already was.




  30 Even though Bank Health Cnty is consistently statistically significant and ∆N etW orth is never more than

marginally significant when controlling for Bank Health Cnty, one must still be cautious in interpreting their relative
importance. Figure 4 plots the bootstrap distribution of coefficients on Bank Health Cnty and ∆N etW orth. The
joint 95% confidence interval for aggregate employment growth includes values where ∆N etW orth matters as much
or more than Bank Health Cnty.


                                                          61
2.7                Appendix

2.7.1              Figures

              .3




                                                                                    1
                                                                                    .8
              .2




                                                                         Probability of lending
    Density




                                                                                     .6
              .1




                                                                                    .4
                                                                                    .2
              0




                   0        10      20       30        40      50                                 0       2       4        6       8       10
                       Distance to Lending Institution (miles)                                        Distance to Nearest Branch (miles)



                                        Figure 2.1: Distribution of Lender Distances
Notes: The left figure shows the distance to the depository institution offering a small business a line of credit from
the 2003 Survey of Small Business Finance, excluding loans in banks more than 50 miles away. The right figure shows
how the probability of a CRA reporting institution making a small business loan in a particular census tract varies
with the distance between the tract centroid and the nearest branch of an institution. Probabilities are determined
by local linear regression on the 0-1 loan indicator using an Epanechnikov kernel with a bandwidth of .2 miles. This
is done for the year 2006.




                                                                    62
                         Employment Growth                                       Non−tradable Growth
                           No County Control                                        No County Control
    .2 .4 .6 .8




                                                               1
                                                               .2 .4 .6 .8
    0




                     0     100           200        300                      0      100           200       300
                             Distance (kms)                                           Distance (kms)


                         Employment Growth                                       Non−tradable Growth
                           Net Worth Control                                        Net Worth Control
                                                               1.5
    −.2 0 .2 .4 .6




                                                               1
                                                               .5
                                                               0




                     0     100           200        300                      0      100           200       300
                             Distance (kms)                                           Distance (kms)


                                    Coefficient on Bank Health                            95% CI


                          Figure 2.2: Effect of Bank Health: Distance Based Instruments
Notes: This figure presents the results of IV regressions as done in Table 4. However, instead of using county or
CBSA market definitions, I use distance based definitions. Specifically, Bank Health Cnty is instrumented using
                                            Db,c Db,c0
                                                       ∆N etW orthc0 where md (c) is the set of counties within dkms
                    P      P
Outside Shock c =      b∈B   c0 ∈{C\md (c)} Dc    Db
of c. The graph plots the coefficient and 95% confidence for Bank Health Cnty for different values of the distance
parameter d. The left panels have total employment growth from 2007 to 2010 as the independent variable, while
the right have non-tradable employment growth. The top panels omit the control for ∆N etW orth, while the bottom
panels include it.




                                                          63
               Bank Health and Growth                                Bank Health and Growth: By Size




                                                              .02
    .8
    .6




                                                              .01
    .4




                                                              0
    .2




                                                              −.01
    0




                                                              −.02
    −.2




          0            5              10            15               0         5              10             15
                           Distance (kms)                                          Distance (kms)

                           Regression Coefficient                        Small, Unhealthy           Small, Healthy
                           95% CI                                        Large, Unhealthy




                   Figure 2.3: Effects of Bank Health on Tract Growth: By Distance
Notes: Both panels demonstrate how the health of banks within a certain distance of a census tract impact the
employment growth from 2007 to 2010. The left panel plots the coefficient and 95% confidence interval from the
regression ∆ln(Emp)t,c = βB Bank Health T ractt (d) + βx0 Xt + δc + t weighting by 2006 employment, following
specification (1) of Table 7. Bank Health T ractt (d) is the deposit weighted health (bank exposure to real estate
appreciation) of the branches within d kms of the tract centroid. The right panel plots the expected growth of tracts
within different categories. “Large” tracts have below the county median share of employment in small establishments,
”Unhealthy” tracts have a value for Bank Health T ract(d) below the county median. The expected growth for each
size-health pair relative to the Large-Healthy category are plotted. These coefficients are derived from regressions
following specification (6) in Table 7.




                                                         64
                                    Figure 2.4: Joint Confidence Regions
Notes: These figures plot the bootstrap coefficients and 95% confidence interval for the coefficients on ∆N etW orth
and Bank Health Cnty. These figures correspond to specifications (3) and (6) in Table 3 and (2) and (4) in Panel
2 of Table 4. The IV specification uses the outside CBSA instrument for bank health. I use 500 replications. The
elongated confidence regions are a consequence of a high correlation between the key explanatory variables. This
shows that although one can be confident that the coefficient on Bank Health Cnty is greater that 0, one can’t
precisely assess the relative magnitude of the banking channel and the demand channel.




                                                        65
2.7.2   Tables

                         Table 2.1: Summary Statistics
                                           Mean     Standard     Percentile       Obs
                                                    Deviation   10th   90th
  Bank Level
  Bank Health                              -0.059     0.070     -0.144   0.001    2092
  Bank × County Growth
  ∆ln(SB Loans)                            -0.038     1.160     -1.269   1.485    20995
  County Level (Weighted by Households)
    Bank Health Cnty                       -0.084     0.042     -0.153   -0.038   944
    ∆N etW orth                            -0.095     0.100     -0.218   -0.006   944
    Outside Shock (County)                 -0.065     0.031     -0.108   -0.030   944
    Outside Shock (CBSA)                   -0.057     0.030     -0.101   -0.025   944
  Employment Growth:2007-2010
    T otal                                 -0.077     0.053     -0.146   -0.012   944
    N ontradable                           -0.056     0.065     -0.112    0.018   944
    T radable                              -0.188     0.156     -0.371   -0.034   944
    HighDependence                         -0.105     0.088     -0.208   -0.009   944
    LowDependence                          -0.062     0.060     -0.124    0.004   944
    Y oung                                 0.267      0.113      0.152    0.392   900
    M ature                                -0.040     0.051     -0.101    0.019   900
  Tract Level (Weighted by Employment)
  ∆ln(Emp tract)                           -0.049     0.272     -0.308    0.196   55843
  Bank Health T ract (3km)                 -0.084     0.043     -0.144   -0.037   46828




                                      66
                          Table 2.2: Growth in Number of Small Loans

                                  (1)           (2)            (3)          (4)            (5)            (6)
 Bank Health                    1.987∗∗       2.105∗∗        2.202∗∗      2.249∗∗
                                (0.711)       (0.751)        (0.763)      (0.793)

 ∆N etW orth                                  -0.265+        0.300+                      -0.0762       0.305∗
                                              (0.151)        (0.155)                    (0.0907)       (0.137)

 Bank Health Cnty                                            -1.618∗∗                                  -1.113∗∗
                                                              (0.558)                                   (0.397)
 Observations                    17519         17519           17519       17519         17519           17519
 R2                              0.147         0.147           0.149       0.185         0.423           0.424
 Fixed Effect                                                              CNTY          BANK           BANK
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of bank×county growth in small business originations on bank
health measures. The dependent variable is the growth in the number of small business loans originated by the bank
in the county from 2008-2010 relative to 2004-2006. Bank Health is the average change in household net worth in
b’s counties, weighted by b’s deposits in the county. ∆N etW orth is the percentage change in household net worth
from falling house prices for the actual county, while Bank Health Cnty is the deposit weighted average value of
Bank Health of the banks in the county. County fixed effects are used in (4), while bank fixed effects are used in
(5) & (6). I additionally control for 2-digit industry shares and the natural logarithm of the number of loans made
from 2004-2006. Standard errors are clustered by bank. I drop any observation in which the bank holding company
acquired another bank within the CBSA, observations in the highest or lowest percentile of growth, and observations
where the bank didn’t have a 2006 branch within the county.




                                                        67
                                                          Table 2.3: Employment Growth: By Tradability

                                                   All Industries                                   Nontradable                                     Tradable
                                           (1)             (2)            (3)            (4)              (5)            (6)            (7)             (8)            (9)
       Bank Health Cnty                  0.497∗∗                        0.279∗         0.630∗∗                         0.642∗∗         0.221                         -0.131
                                        (0.0977)                        (0.111)        (0.102)                         (0.108)        (0.216)                       (0.292)

       ∆N etW orth                                      0.201∗∗         0.105+                         0.214∗∗        -0.00568                       0.125           0.170
68




                                                       (0.0477)        (0.0577)                       (0.0493)        (0.0655)                      (0.0953)        (0.124)
       Observations                        944            944             944             944            944             944            944            944            944
       R2                                 0.414          0.413           0.423           0.241          0.208           0.241          0.075          0.077          0.077
       Standard errors in parentheses
       + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01
     Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of county level employment growth from 2007 to 2010 on measures of bank health and shocks to housing net worth. The
     dependent variable is the growth in total employment in 1-3, the growth in non-tradable employment (restaurants and retail establishments) in 4-6, and growth in tradable
     employment in 7-9. ∆N etW orth is the percentage change in net worth of the households of a county and Bank Health is average multimarket exposure to ∆N etW orth of local
     banks weighted by local deposit share. Controls for the share of employment in each 2 digit NAICS industry are included in each regression. I weight by the total households
     in the county and cluster the standard error by state.
             Table 2.4: Employment Growth: IV with Out of Market Shocks

                                   All Industries                Nontradable                    Tradable
 Market               CNTY                      CBSA          CNTY           CBSA         CNTY          CBSA
                        (1)                      (2)           (3)            (4)          (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: No County Control
 Bank Health Cnty 0.475∗∗                      0.466∗∗        0.616∗∗       0.660∗∗        0.244         0.0604
                     (0.0709)                 (0.0718)       (0.0903)       (0.112)       (0.216)       (0.217)
 Observations          944                       944            944           944           944           944
 R2                   0.414                     0.414          0.241         0.240         0.075         0.073
 F                   419.853                  216.516        419.853        216.516       419.853       216.516

 Panel 2: Own County Control
 Bank Health Cnty    0.272∗                    0.270+         0.599∗∗       0.715∗∗       0.0202         -0.440
                     (0.118)                   (0.153)        (0.179)       (0.230)       (0.376)       (0.449)

 ∆N etW orth                     0.107          0.108        0.00894        -0.0308        0.118         0.276
                                (0.0725)      (0.0781)       (0.0910)       (0.103)       (0.156)       (0.173)
 Observations                      944           944            944           944           944           944
 R2                              0.423          0.423          0.241         0.240         0.077         0.076
 F                              166.787       127.954        166.787        127.954       166.787       127.954
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from IV regressions of county level employment growth from 2007 to 2010 on
measures of bank health and shocks to housing net worth. The dependent variable is the growth in total employment
in 1-3, the growth in non-tradable employment (restaurants and retail establishments) in 4-6, and growth in tradable
employment in 7-9. The endogenous variables is Bank Health, which is average multimarket exposure to ∆N etW orth
of local banks weighted by local deposit share. This is instrumented for using bank exposure to real estate declines
from other counties in odd columns, and other CBSAs in even columns. Controls for the share of employment in
each 2 digit NAICS industry are included in each regression. In panel 2, I additionally control for ∆N etW orth, the
percentage change in net worth of the households of a county. I weight by the total households in the county and
cluster the standard error by state.




                                                        69
                  Table 2.5: Employment Growth: By Financial Dependence

                                             OLS                  IV:Outside Cnty              IV:Outside CBSA
 Financial Dependence:   High        Low                           High           Low           High           Low
                          (1)         (2)                           (3)           (4)            (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: No County Control
 Bank Health Cnty       0.661∗∗    0.391∗∗                       0.627∗∗    0.394∗∗            0.689∗∗    0.363∗∗
                        (0.109)     (0.103)                      (0.100) (0.0835)              (0.115) (0.0870)
 Difference:                   .27+                                     .233+                         .325∗
                               (.15)                                   (.131)                        (.144)
 Observations             944         944                          944         944               944         944
 R2                      0.339       0.264                        0.338       0.264             0.338       0.264

 Panel 2: Own County Control
 Bank Health Cnty       0.451∗                     0.291∗∗        0.406∗        0.323∗         0.593∗∗        0.251
                       (0.199)                    (0.0955)        (0.201)       (0.139)        (0.216)       (0.195)

 ∆N etW orth                        0.101      0.0485              0.117      0.0375           0.0531      0.0622
                                   (0.0698) (0.0591)             (0.0792) (0.0804)            (0.0790) (0.0937)
 Difference:                              .161                           .083                         .342
                                         (.221)                         (.245)                       (.291)
 Observations                        944         944                944         944              944         944
 R2                                 0.341       0.265              0.341       0.265            0.340       0.265
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of county level employment growth from 2007 to 2010 on
measures of bank health and shocks to housing net worth. The dependent variable is the growth in employment in
industries with a high dependence on external finance in odd columns, and growth in industries with low financial
depdendence in even columns. The first two columns are estimated with OLS, while the last four instrument for
Bank Health Cnty using only the component coming from other counties or CBSAs. The difference in the coefficients
for highly and lowly financially dependent industries is reported below the regression coefficient. Controls for the share
of employment in each 2 digit NAICS industry are included in each regression. In panel 2, I additionally control for
∆N etW orth, the percentage change in net worth of the households of a county. I weight by the total households in
the county and cluster the standard error by state.




                                                           70
                             Table 2.6: Employment Growth: By Age

                                         OLS                  IV:Outside Cnty            IV:Outside CBSA
                     Young         Old                       Young           Old          Young           Old
                       (1)         (2)                        (3)            (4)           (5)            (6)
 Panel 1: No County Control
 Bank Health Cnty 0.853∗∗ 0.384∗∗                            0.794∗∗ 0.361∗∗             0.926∗∗ 0.257∗∗
                     (0.171) (0.114)                         (0.163) (0.0917)            (0.120) (0.0640)
 Difference:                .469∗                                   .432∗                      .669∗∗
                            (.206)                                 (.187)                      (.136)
 Observations          900         900                         900        900              900        900
   2
 R                    0.299      0.286                        0.298      0.286            0.298     0.279

 Panel 2: Own County Control
 Bank Health Cnty 0.599+                      0.349∗∗         0.491        0.294∗        0.877∗        0.0229
                     (0.316)                  (0.117)        (0.310)       (0.127)       (0.357)       (0.204)

 ∆N etW orth                     0.121      0.0165            0.157     0.0353           0.0268      0.127
                                (0.128)    (0.0648)          (0.135) (0.0775)            (0.168) (0.108)
 Difference:                            .25                         .198                        .854∗
                                      (.337)                       (.335)                      (.411)
 Observations                     900         900              900        900              900        900
 R2                              0.301       0.286            0.301      0.286            0.299      0.272
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of county level employment growth from 2007 to 2010 on
measures of bank health and shocks to housing net worth. The dependent variable is the growth in employment for
young firms (five years and younger) in odd columns, and growth in mature firms in even columns. The first two
columns are estimated with OLS, while the last four instrument for Bank Health Cnty using only the component
coming from other counties or CBSAs. The difference in the coefficients for young and mature firms is reported below
the regression coefficient. Controls for the share of employment in each 2 digit NAICS industry are included in each
regression. In panel 2, I additionally control for ∆N etW orth, the percentage change in net worth of the households
of a county. I weight by the total households in the county and cluster the standard error by state.




                                                        71
                                                         Table 2.7: Tract Employment Growth

                                                      Continuous Health Measure                                  High Bank Health Indicator
                                               (1)           (2)            (3)           (4)             (5)            (6)            (7)            (8)
      Bank Health T ract                     0.391∗∗       0.240+         0.139∗       0.00846         0.0135∗∗      -0.000112       0.00848∗∗       0.00263
                                            (0.0909)       (0.121)       (0.0598)      (0.0798)       (0.00384)      (0.00698)       (0.00268)      (0.00410)

      Bank Health T ract × SM                              0.222+                        0.262∗∗                      0.0209+                        0.0121∗
                                                           (0.112)                      (0.0832)                      (0.0109)                      (0.00471)

      SM                                                   0.00901                      -0.00139                      -0.0199∗                      -0.0301∗∗
72




                                                          (0.00970)                    (0.00790)                     (0.00900)                      (0.00618)
      Observations                           45923          45901         45923          45901          45923          45901          45923           45901
      R2                                     0.103          0.104         0.055           0.057         0.103           0.104         0.055           0.057
      Fixed Effect                           CNTY          CNTY           CNTY           CNTY           CNTY           CNTY           CNTY           CNTY
      Weighted?                                Y              Y             N               N             Y               Y             N               N
      Standard errors in parentheses
      + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

     Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of tract level employment growth from 2007 to 2010 on tract level measures of bank health and county
     fixed effects. In the first four columns, Bank Health T ract is the average health of the banks within 3km of the tract centroid, weighted by the deposits in
     branches within 3km of the tract. In the last four columns, Bank Health T ract is an indicator for whether the aforementioned measure is above the county
     median. I additionally control for 2-digit NAICS employment shares of the tract in 2006. Even columns additionally include an interaction for whether the
     tract is above the county median in terms of the share of employment in small establishments. Regressions are weighted by 2006 tract employment in 1,2,5,
     &6 and unweighted in the rest. Standard errors are clustered by state. Observations in the highest and lowest percentile of employment growth are dropped.
                             Table 2.8: Evidence of Wage Adjustment

                                 ALL          Under        Less Than            High         Some        College
                                              25 yrs       High School         School       College
                       (1)                     (2)             (3)               (4)          (5)           (6)
 Panel 1: Wage Growth
 Bank Health Cnty     0.157                   0.383∗∗          0.286∗∗         0.231∗        0.172        0.143
                     (0.113)                 (0.0852)         (0.0879)         (0.101)      (0.109)      (0.126)
 Observations          929                      931              927             929          928          919
   2
 R                    0.161                    0.378            0.340           0.238        0.179        0.127

 Panel 2: Employment Growth
 Bank Health Cnty 0.344∗∗                    0.480∗∗          0.509∗∗           0.241       0.330∗∗      0.319∗
                     (0.124)                 (0.144)          (0.133)          (0.149)      (0.116)      (0.122)
 Observations          932                     932              928              932          932          931
 R2                   0.249                   0.268            0.308            0.281        0.237        0.191
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of 2007 to 2010 employment or wage growth within an education
category on bank health. The first panel uses wage growth as the dependent variable, while the second uses stable
employment growth. The wage in a given year is the income of stable workers divided by the number of stable workers
of a given education type. Column 1 includes all workers, while the proceeding columns include only (2) workers under
25, (3) less than high school, (4) high school, (5) some college, and (6) college. Bank Health is average multimarket
exposure to ∆N etW orth of local banks weighted by local deposit share. Controls for the share of employment in each
2 digit NAICS industry are included in each regression. I weight by the total households in the county and cluster
the standard error by state.




                                                         73
                          Table 2.9: County Growth: Health of 2002 Branches

                                            All Industries                       Nontradable                          Tradable
                                           (1)              (2)               (3)               (4)              (5)               (6)
  Bank Health Cnty                       0.507∗∗          0.273∗            0.637∗∗           0.672∗∗           0.218            -0.217
                                        (0.0949)          (0.134)          (0.0997)           (0.160)          (0.203)          (0.342)

  ∆N etW orth                                             0.107                               -0.0159                            0.200
                                                         (0.0703)                            (0.0837)                           (0.156)
  Observations                             944              944                944              944               944             944
  R2                                      0.414            0.423              0.241            0.241             0.075           0.077
  Standard errors in parentheses
  +   p < 0.10,    ∗   p < 0.05,   ∗∗   p < .01
Notes: This table reports coefficients from IV regressions of county level employment growth from 2007 to 2010 on measures of bank health
and shocks to housing net worth. The dependent variable is the growth in total employment in 1-3, the growth in non-tradable employment
(restaurants and retail establishments) in 4-6, and growth in tradable employment in 7-9. ∆N etW orth is the percentage change in net worth of
the households of a county and Bank Health Cnty is average multimarket exposure to ∆N etW orth of local banks weighted by local deposit
share. I instrument for Bank Health Cnty using the equivalent definition as in the text except with 2002 branch deposits. Controls for the
share of employment in each 2 digit NAICS industry are included in each regression. I weight by the total households in the county and cluster
the standard error by state.




                                                                     74
                      Table 2.10: Tract Growth: Health of 2002 Branches

                                 Continuous Health Measure                 High Bank Health Indicator
                                   (1)                  (2)                   (3)                   (4)
 Bank Health T ract              0.391∗∗              0.181∗                0.00991              0.0191∗∗
                                 (0.127)             (0.0898)              (0.00779)            (0.00629)
 Observations                     44898               44898                  44898                44898
 R2                               0.105                0.056                 0.105                 0.056
 Fixed Effect                    CNTY                 CNTY                  CNTY                  CNTY
 Weighted?                          Y                    N                     Y                     N
 Standard errors in parentheses
 + p < 0.10, ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < .01

Notes: This table coefficients from IV regressions of tract level employment growth from 2007 to 2010 on tract level
measures bank health and county fixed effects. In the first two columns, Bank Health T ract is the average health
of the banks within 3km of the tract centroid, weighted by the deposits in branches within 3km of the tract. In the
third and fourth column, Bank Health T ract is an indicator for whether the aforementioned measure is above the
county median. I instrument for Bank Health T ract using the equivalent definition as from the text, except with
2002 branch locations and deposits. I additionally control for 2-digit NAICS employment shares of the tract in 2006.
Regressions are weighted by 2006 tract employment in 1 & 3 unweighted in 2 & 4. Standard errors are clustered by
state. Observations in the highest and lowest percentile of employment growth are dropped.




                                                        75
2.7.3    Theory Appendix

To motivate the empirical work, I present a simple model of bank credit and employment. First, I

derive how how banks choose their aggregate lending and allocate credit across counties. Then, I

calculate how county and industry employment are affected by credit and demand shocks. In the

end, I discuss the implications of the model for the different empirical approaches.


Model

Bank’s Problem            Suppose that banks engage in monopolistic competition in the provision of

business loans. A borrower i in county c uses a CES composite of borrowing from a continuum of

banks to engage in production. They choose the amount to borrow from banks b, Lbc,i , so as to
                                              
                                           ! −1
          R b b               R b −1                            b
minimize    rc,i Lc,i db s.t.  (Lc,i )  db      = Lc,i . Where rc,i is the interest rate charged by
         Ωc                         Ωc
bank b to borrower i in county c, Ωc is the set of banks operating in county c and Lc,i is aggregate

borrowing. This implies a demand curve.

                                                                    b
                                                                   rc,i
                                                Lbc,i = Lc,i (          )−
                                                                   rc,i

              R b 1−       1
where rc,i = ( (rc,i ) db) 1− is the cost of bank borrowing.
               Ωc
   Given a certain level of aggregate lending Lb , the bank will allocate credit across borrowers in

order to maximize profit subject to demand curves and the adding up constraint. Denoting the set

of counties b operates in Cb and the set of borrowers in the county Ic , b’s maximization problem is:

                                         X X
                          maximize                   Lbc,i rc,i
                                                            b
                              b }
                            {rc,i
                                         c∈Cb i∈Ic
                                                                                     b
                                         X X                                        rc,i
                          subject to                 Lbc,i = Lb , {Lbc,i = Lc,i (        )− } ∀c, i
                                                                                    rc,i
                                         c∈Cb i∈Ic


   This results in a constant optimal lending rate for bank b:

                                                            Db 1
                                                 rb = (        )  ∀i, c                                         (2.3)
                                                            Lb

where Db =                      
               P P
                          Lc,i rc,i measures the level of demand for loans from b. This is increasing in the
              c∈Cb i∈Ic
aggregate demand for bank finance among clients and in the interest rate charged by competitors.

   Next, to determine the optimal size of the bank’s loan portfolio, suppose that the marginal cost
                                                                               Lb
of funds for a bank is an increasing function c() of its leverage              Eb
                                                                                  ,    where E b is the bank’s equity.



                                                              76
Then the first order condition implicitly defining the bank’s optimal lending is:

                                                  − 1 Db 1       Lb
                                                      ( b )  = c( b )
                                                      L          E

This equation equates marginal revenue to marginal cost, and thus defines the bank’s supply curve.

Log-linearizing this equation, and combining it with the demand curve in (3), we find that the

growth in lending and interest rates as a function of the growth in demand and equity:


                                          ˆ b = η BE E
                                          L          ˆ b + (1 − η BE )D
                                                                      ˆb                                (2.4)
                                                 b               b




                                                         ηbBE ˆ b ˆb)
                                                 rˆb =       (D − E                                     (2.5)
                                                           
                                   b
                            b    ( L b ) −1 −1
where ηbBE = (1 + (c0 ( E
                         L
                           b)
                                   E
                                     b )   )     parameterizes the degree of bank financial constraints. Note
                                c( L b )
                                  E

that growth in lending is more related to equity growth if the elasticity of marginal cost with respect

to leverage is high. In the extreme, if banks have a constant marginal cost of funds up until they

hit a binding leverage constraint, ηbBE would be 1 for any bank at the regulatory capital ratio, and

0 for any bank below it.


Bank County Lending              Summing over the industry demand curves within a county, and using

that the optimal bank interest rate is constant at the bank level, we get that the county level lending

for b is Lbc = (rb )−   Lc,i rc . Thus the growth in lending at the bank-county level is:
                       P
                     i∈Ic



                                           ˆ b = −ˆ
                                           L            ˆc
                                                   rb + D
                                             c
                                                                                                        (2.6)
                                                          ˆb − E
                                                 = −ηbBE (D    ˆb) + D
                                                                     ˆc


                           Lc,i rc denotes the level of demand for bank loans in county c and rc =
                    P
     Where Dc ≡
                    i∈Ic
                1
( (rb )1− db) 1− is the interest rate charged for bank lending in county c.
 R
Ωc


Firm’s Problem

To endogenize the loan demand, and understand how changes in credit spreads impact employment,

consider the following optimization problem. A representative firm in industry i in county c produces




                                                           77
output Yc,i with a constant returns to scale production function using labor Nc,i such that:


                                                                      Yc,i = Ac,i Nc,i


The wage bill wc Nc,i is financed by a combination of bank finance Lc,i and direct finance dc,i
                                          c,i                     δ       1−δc,i
according to the relationship wc Nc,i = Lc,i  dc,i                                 . Recall the cost of bank finance is rc and denote

the cost of direct finance ρ. The firm’s cost minimization problem is:


                                                                                c,i                   δ   1−δc,i
                                           min rc Lc,i + ρdc,i s.t. wc Nc,i = Lc,i  dc,i


The marginal cost of output and demand for bank funds are then:

                                                                                               wc
                                                           mcc,i = co rcδc,i ρ1−δi,c
                                                                                               Ac,i

                                                                                  δc,i −1
                                                                              rc
                                                          Lc,i = bo                           wc Nc,i
                                                                              ρ

Where co and bo are constants.31

   Assuming perfect competition and a unit elastic demand curve, expenditure on i’s good is fixed
                                                                                                            Xc,i
at Xc,i and output is priced at marginal cost. Consequently Yc,i =                                          mci,c .   Normalizing ρ to one for

notational simplicity, labor demand is

                                                                  Yc,i                     −1
                                                       Nc,i =          = Xc,i co rcδc,i wc
                                                                  Ac,i

   Combining the previous two expressions gives us the demand for bank finance:

                                                                                      Xc,i
                                                                      Lc,i = δc,i
                                                                                       rc

Aggregate Employment Effects Log linearizing the firm’s labor demand:


                                                            ˆc,i = X
                                                            N      ˆ c,i − δc,i rˆc − w
                                                                                      ˆc


   To determine Xc,i , let expenditure growth be a weighted average of national consumption growth
ˆ
¯ and local consumption growth, with weight θc,i on local consumption growth. Furthermore, let
C,
                −δ
                                                               1−δc,i
                                                        δc,i
 31 c
        o   = δc,i c,i (1 − δc,i )δc,i −1 , bo =       1−δc,i




                                                                               78
                                                               ˆc ≡ w
local consumption growth be determined by the growth in income W         ˆc and housing wealth
                                                                    ˆc + N
ˆ c with elasticities η XW and η XH respectively. Growth in expenditure for an industry’s output is
H

then:
                                ˆ c,i = (1 − θc,i )Cˆ¯ + θc,i (η XW W
                                X                                   ˆ c + η XH H
                                                                               ˆ c)


   To pin down wages, let the inverse labor supply curve be wc = Ncψ , then total payments to labor
                                               ˆ c = (ψ + 1)N
are wc Nc = Ncψ+1 . This implies income growth W            ˆc . Combining this with the previous

two equations thus yields the county×industry employment growth:


                             ˆc,i = α(θc,i ) + θc,i η XH H
                             N                           ˆ c − δc,i rˆc + β GE (θc,i )N
                                                                                      ˆc           (2.7)


Where α(θc,i ) = (1 − θc,i )Cˆ
                             ¯ denotes the growth in demand from national sources, and β GE =

θη XW (ψ + 1) − ψ summarizes the general equilibrium effect of changes in aggregate labor demand

on industry labor demand.

   This equation says that a decline in house values reduces local demand (assuming η XH > 0) and

impacts employment in industries which are dependant on local demand (i.e. θc,i is high). This is

the channel emphasized in Mian and Sufi (2014). Also, an increase in the cost of bank credit impacts

employment in firms which are bank dependent (δc,i is high). This is the channel emphasized by

this paper and Chodorow-Reich (2014). Third there are general equilibrium effects which depend on

the tradability of the industry. A contraction in employment lowers the cost of labor for all firms,

however there is an offsetting effect on firms which are dependent on local demand, as the decline

in income reduces expenditure.

   To calculate aggregate employment growth, sum over the growth rates of the industries within

a county (weighting by initial employment) to get:


                                      ˆc = µc (α(θc ) + θc η XH H
                                      N                         ˆ c − δc rˆc )                     (2.8)


                  1
where µc ≡   1−β GE (θc )
                            is a multiplier reflecting the extent of general equilibrium wage and income

effects and θc and δc denote the (weighted) average value of the corresponding industry level param-

eters across the industries within the county.


Implication for Empirical Approaches

Small Business Lending, County Fixed Effects Equation (6) provides the formula for the

growth in lending at the county level. It has a supply component corresponding to changes in

                                                         79
the interest rate the bank charges, and a demand component reflecting the availability of credit

from competitors and the demand for the firm’s product. Regressing county lending growth on

bank health (denoted BH b ) without county fixed effects would produce a point estimate: β L,BH =
      b    b           ˆ c ,BH b )
 cov(ˆ
      r ,BH )
   var(BH b )
              +   cov(D
                    var(BH b )
                                   .   This includes both the effect on interest rates, and on demand. To

isolate the effect of bank health on the cost of credit, I add county fixed effects to absorb the
ˆ c . This should produce the point estimate reflecting the impact of bank health on lending rates:
D
                     b      b
β L,BH |dc =  cov(ˆ
                   r ,BH )
                var(BH b )

   Similarly, using a bank fixed effect allows me to isolate supply shocks and test how changes in

housing net worth impacts demand. Regressing county lending growth on the shock to housing
                                                                                             cov(Dˆ b ,H
                                                                                                       ˆc)
           ˆ and bank fixed effects should provide an estimate: β L,H |δ =
net worth, H,                                                                                        ˆc) .   The fact
                                                                                                    c
                                                                        b                      var(H

that this is found to be indistinguishable from 0, and slightly negative, indicates that the decline in

lending wasn’t due to falling demand in places with declining housing net worth.


Employment Approaches 1& 2 Equation (8) calculates employment growth as a function of
                                                            ˆ c . Assume that Bank Health Cnty
the credit supply shock rˆc and the housing net worth shock H

(denoted BHc for brevity) isn’t related to demand except through it’s influence on lending rates so

that rˆc = η rB BHc + uc , where the residual is orthogonal to demand, then equation 8 becomes:

                                                                                   
                                 ˆc = µc α(θc ) + θc η DH H
                                 N                        ˆ c − δc η rB BHc − δc uc                             (2.9)


                                                                                 ˆ c and the controls
   Approach 1 directly estimates this equation using ∆N etW orthc to control for H

for industry shares to control for differences in θc . If the model is correctly specified and the variables
                                                                                        ∂N ˆ ∂ rˆ
are exogenous, the coefficient on BHc should be µδη rB (or more plainly:                ∂ rˆ ∂BH ).

                                       ˆ c to be exogenous, a condition which is unlikely to hold
   However, direct estimation requires H

as unobservables increasing demand for labor will impact house prices as a consequence. Thus

the second approach is to omit the control, and instrument for Bank Health Cnty using only the

exposure of banks to falling house prices in markets which don’t directly impact local employment.


Employment Approach 3: Difference in Differences by Bank Dependence Note from

equation (7) that a regression of employment growth in an industry i on Bank Health Cnty will

produce a coefficient:

                                               ˆ BHc )
                                           cov(H,           cov(ˆ
                                                                r, BHc )                  ˆ , BHc )
                                                                                      cov(N
               plim βiN,BH = θi η XH                   − δi              + β GE (θi )
                                            var(BHc )        var(BHc )                 var(BHc )



                                                          80
Suppose that industries differ only by their bank dependence, with the difference in importance of

bank credit between the high and the low group being denoted ∆δ ≡ δhigh               dep    − δlow   dep .   Then the

difference in point estimates for high dependence and low dependence firms would be:


                               N,BH        N,BH                cov(ˆ
                                                                   r, BHc )
                         plim(βhigh dep − βlow dep ) = ∆δ                   = ∆δη rB
                                                                var(BHc )

Thus a positive differential would demonstrate that Bank Health Cnty impacts the supply of credit,

since the high and the low group experience the same shocks to demand and wages.


Reconciliation with Mian and Sufi               My findings suggest that declining house prices translate

to employment losses due to a contraction in bank credit. This can be reconciled with the finding in

Mian and Sufi (2014) that deficient aggregate demand was an important driver in the relationship

between house price movements and employment.

   Note from (7) that a completely tradable firm (θi =0) would experience employment growth:


                   ˆc,perfectly tradable = Cˆ¯ − δc,i rˆc − ψ N
                   N                                          ˆc
                                                                                            
                                        = Cˆ¯ − δc,i rˆc − ψµc α(θc ) + θc η XH H
                                                                                ˆ c − δc rˆc


This shows that a contraction in credit has an ambiguous effect on tradable employment. On one

hand, it costs more to borrow (δc,i rˆc ↑), on the other labor becomes cheaper due to constraints at

other firms (ψµc δc rˆc ↑).

   More generally, a regression of employment growth on house price growth would produce the

estimate:


                                                     cov(ˆ  ˆ c)
                                                         r, H                     ˆ, H
                                                                              cov(N   ˆ c)
                       plim βiN,H = θi η XH − δi                 + β GE (θi )
                                                      var(Hˆ c)                var(Hˆ c)

   Now, consider the difference in growth rates in two groups of firms which differ only in tradability.

Non-tradable industries are more reliant on local demand (∆θ ≡ θc,nontrade − θc,trade > 0). Then

the difference in the effect of a house price decline in tradable and non-tradable industries will be




                                                        81
estimated as

                                                        ˆc , H
                                                    cov(N    ˆ c)
            H           H
     plim( βnontrade − βtrade ) = ∆θη XH + ∆β GE
                                                     V ar(Hˆ c)
                                                                   ˆc , H
                                                               cov(N    ˆ c)
                                = ∆θη XH + ∆θ(η XW (ψ + 1)
                                                                      ˆ
                                                                V ar(Hc )
                                                                                                
                                                                                                !
                                                                                              ˆ
                                                                                                  
                                      XH          XW                       XH      cov(ˆ
                                                                                        r c , H c 
                                = ∆θ  η      + (η       (ψ  + 1)   µ θ c η    − δc
                                                                                                   
                                      | {z }
                                               |       {z      }                    V ar(H ˆ c)  
                                      Direct Sensitivity of Demand |            {z               }
                                       Effect      to Labor Demand             Labor Demand
                                                                                  Change


                                                                                                       ˆ
   This equation shows that if falling house prices adversely impacts the supply of credit ( cov(ˆrc ,Hc
                                                                                              V ar(Hˆ ) <
                                                                                                       c

0), then this will impact non-tradable industries the most. Thus a greater sensitivity of employment

growth with respect to house price growth doesn’t prove the existence of a housing wealth effect.

Even if η XH = 0, you would still find that non-tradable industries respond more.

   Intuitively a decline in credit in a county has three effects: (1) a direct effect on labor demand by

increasing the cost of capital for bank dependent firms, (2) an offsetting general equilibrium effect

on the cost of labor through declining wages, and (3) an amplifying effect through the reduction

in local demand due to lower wages or employment. The first two effects hit both tradable, and

non-tradable industries, while the third effect in only borne by non-tradable industries. In short,

although the decline in labor demand in non-tradable industries suggests a decline in local demand,

this does not necessarily rule out credit supply. Weak labor market conditions stemming from credit

disruptions can also cause spending to decline, thus harming industries which are reliant on local

demand.




                                                   82
Chapter 3


A Spatial Measure of Banking

Competition

3.1        Introduction

Banks play a fundamental role in the allocation of capital within an economy. When these banks

can exert market power, it may have a significant adverse effect on the ability of the economy to

function efficiently. An understanding of the competitive pressures within the banking system is

thus of vital importance.

   The first step of any empirical analysis of banking competition is proper measurement. Although

there is a vast literature attempting to measure the influence of bank competition, there is still no

consensus on how competition itself should actually be measured. When regulators are trying to

determine the probable competitive effects of a merger, their starting point is to use a Herfindahl-

Hirschman Index (HHI) of deposits within a market, where the market is defined roughly as an

MSA or a rural county.1 This methodology is also common in the academic literature when trying

to either control for bank competition or determine its impacts.

   However, this market definition is at odds with the literature on distance and banking. Studies

utilizing various sources of data and time periods have found that individuals and small businesses

rely predominantly on very nearby banks, and that banks price discriminate based on location. If

banks are able to geographically segment the market and exert market power in those segments, a
                                                                    B
  1 The                                                                   s2b where sb is the share of the total deposits
                                                                    P
          conventional Herfindahl measure is defined as: HHImkt =
                                                                    b=1
in the market held by bank b.



                                                       83
market may be uncompetitive without being concentrated. The conventional MSA level Herfindahl

is a flawed measure of competition because it fails to take into account the location of banks within

the MSA. Thus, while it may address the ability of banks to collude on pricing, it fails to pickup

how the location of banks within a market can impact market power arising from spatial frictions

in lending.

   The primary contribution of this paper is the introduction of a new measure of banking con-

centration which takes into account the local nature of banking. Specifically, I create a tract level

measure of concentration, which amounts to the deposit Herfindahl for all branches within a certain

distance of the tract centroid. My market level measure, referred to from here on out as the Local

Herfindahl, is then the average concentration of the tracts within the market. This measure of

concentration reflects both the availability of competitors within a market as well as the degree to

which they geographically segment the market.

   With this new measure of concentration, I weigh in on three existing questions in the banking

literature. (1) Does bank market structure impact pricing and profitability? (2) What is the proper

geographic extent of banking markets? (3) Is bank market power detrimental to the ability of young

firms to obtain finance?

   The first question this paper addresses is how bank market structure impacts the ability of

banks to behave uncompetitively. If concentration results in less competition, this should impact a

bank’s pricing decisions and ultimate profitability (the Structure-Conduct-Performance hypothesis).

Consistent with this, concentration has been found to be associated with low deposit rates (Berger

and Hannan, 1989; Heitfield and Prager, 2004), deposit rates which are less prone to rise with market

rates (Hannan and Berger, 1991; Neumark and Sharpe, 1992), high loan rates (Hannan, 1991; Hannan

and Liang, 1995), and high profitability (Pilloff and Rhoades, 2002; Rhoades, 1995). However, other

papers have questioned the hypothesis that market structure impacts bank performance and argue

that concentration may reflect high market shares of more efficient firms, and thus higher profitability

(Smirlock, 1985; Rhoades, 1985; Evanoff and Fortier, 1988; Berger, 1995). Additionally, Weiss (1989)

finds that the positive relationship between concentration and loan rates is inconstant across different

studies.

   Measuring concentration using the Local Herfindahl results in stronger findings in support of

the Structure-Conduct-Performance hypothesis. Local concentration is consistently more predictive

of bank market power than conventional concentration. A one standard deviation increase in the

conventional MSA Herfindahl raises average loan rates by 3 basis points. A one standard deviation

increase in the new Local Herfindahl, even controlling for the conventional Herfindahl, raises lending

                                                  84
rates by 10 basis points and makes the conventional Herfindahl insignificant. Similar results holds for

other indicators of bank market power; banks in locally concentrated markets charge higher interest

rates on commercial and industrial loans, have higher service charges, offer lower deposit rates, and

as a result experience higher net profit margins and returns on equity.

    The greater magnitude and significance for local concentration suggests that previous studies

using the conventional Herfindahl suffered from attenuation bias, possibly explaining the lack of

consistent findings. Furthermore, since variation in the Local Herfindahl comes from different loca-

tion patterns within the market instead of only differences in aggregate market shares, the results

are less likely to be explained by heterogeneity in bank efficiency.

    The second question is how one should define a banking market. Regulators define markets at

roughly the level of the MSA or the rural county. This market definition has been supported by

numerous studies of bank pricing and profitability (Heitfield, 1999; Heitfield and Prager, 2004; Pilloff

and Rhoades, 2002). However, several authors have argued that financial innovations and deregula-

tion has resulted in markets which may be statewide or national (Jackson III and Eisenbeis, 1997;

Radecki, 1998; Petersen and Rajan, 2002). In the other direction, the observation of a disproportion-

ate reliance on local banks (Kwast et al., 1997; Brevoort and Hannan, 2006; Brevoort and Wolken,

2009) and on spatial price discrimination (Degryse and Ongena, 2005; Agarwal and Hauswald, 2010;

Bellucci et al., 2013) raises the possibility of bank markets being substantially smaller due to either

transport costs or information problems associated with distant lending. An understanding of the

appropriate market definition is important for both the regulators responsible for approving mergers,

and academics studying the sources and implications of bank market power.

    My measure of concentration is well suited for addressing this question because it includes a

distance parameter pertaining to how far from a tract a branch can be and still be included in the

tract’s market. I can thus test how the relationship between concentration and bank pricing varies

depending on the market definition. I find that the Local Herfinadhl with a distance parameter of 4

km is most predictive of lending rates. Additionally, I find that the Tract Herfinadhl reflecting the

concentration in the 8kms surrounding a bank’s branches is most predictive of its lending rates.2

    The final question I address is how market structure impacts firm financial constraints and

the allocation of capital. Bank market power may help young risky firms obtain credit, as banks

will be more able to build a relationship with them and earn rents in the future (Information
   2 Note that these measures reflect different things. The Tract Herfindahl reflects the availability of competitors

within a certain distance of a bank’s branches. The Local Herfindahl is the average concentration of the tracts within
a conventionally defined market. This accounts for the fact that segmentation elsewhere in an MSA may impact the
outside option of nearby borrowers.



                                                         85
Hypothesis). Consistent with this, Petersen and Rajan (1995) and Cetorelli and Gambera (2001)

find concentration benefits young firms. Alternatively, young firms are less able to fund themselves

or obtain non-bank external finance, making financial frictions due to bank market power potentially

more damaging (Market Power Hypothesis). Cetorelli and Strahan (2006) and Chong et al. (2013)

find that young firms particularly struggle in concentrated markets.

    One reason for the lack of consistent findings could be the inability to measure market power

properly with the conventional Herfinadahl. The within US studies use MSA/rural county market

definitions, while most of the cross country studies assume national banking markets. Ignoring the

spatial distribution of bank branches would be particularly problematic for studying small business

lending, as the opaque information environment exacerbates asymmetric information problems.3

Furthermore, the small loan sizes make any distance related costs to lending proportionally more of

a deterrent.

    In order to analyze how market structure relates to firm financial constraints, I test how bank

market structure impacts the ability of firms to expand following a shock to investment demand.

Imperfect financial markets make firm growth more dependent on the availability of internal funds

than on demand, reducing the synchronization between the firm’s growth and the national growth

rate of the industry. I find that in locally concentrated markets firm employment growth is less

responsive to changes in national employment growth, especially for firms less than 6 years old.

However, the conventional MSA concentration is not significantly related to this elasticity for young

firms, suggesting a weaker correlation with firm financial constraints.

    Taken together, this paper provides evidence that banks obtain market power stemming from

spatial frictions in lending. More segmented markets allow higher bank markups and result in higher

financial constraints for young firms. This is significant in understanding the potential effects of the

recent consolidation of the banking system. Since the removal of interstate branching restrictions

following the 1994 Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act, there has been a

dramatic consolidation of the banking system resulting in more concentrated MSAs. However, the

remaining banks have been more spread across sub-markets within MSAs, causing concentration at

finer levels to decline. As local concentration is found to be what matters for bank pricing, this

suggests an increase in the the competitiveness of the banking sector since 1994, while previous

findings with regard to the trend and effect of market concentration would suggest the opposite.
   3 Claessens and Laeven (2005) and Carb´ o-Valverde et al. (2009) present evidence that concentration fails to measure
bank market power as is relevant to young firms. They find that competition is beneficial to growth, when measured
using New Empirical Industrial Organization based measures of market power. However, competition as measured by
low concentration is found to be either unimportant or to have the opposite effect.



                                                          86
   The remainder of the paper will proceed as follows: Section 2 documents the evidence that

banking is a local activity, and motivates the new measure of concentration. Section 3 describes

the construction of the Local Herfindahl, and compares it to the conventional measure. Section 4

justifies that the new measure better relates to lending rates, deposit rates, and profitability. Section

5 presents an application to the study of financial frictions for young firms. Section 6 concludes.



3.2     Background and Motivation

3.2.1    Bank Concentration and Competition

A primary factor determining the effectiveness of the banking system is its competitiveness. A

monopolist bank may be able to offer low rates on deposits and high rates on loans, bringing

about an inefficiently low quantity of intermediation. Such a bank may also face minimal costs to

inefficiency and be able to enjoy a quiet life with minimal effort engaged in screening investments,

thus harming allocative efficiency. Finally, a bank with sufficient market power may act so as to

support incumbents to whom they’ve made loans at the expense of new entrants and inhibit the

process of creative destruction. Given that a well developed financial system is critical for economic

growth (King and Levine, 1993; Levine, 2005), supporting competition in the banking sector is an

important policy goal.

   One of the determinants of the competitiveness of the banking sector seems to the availability

of competitors in the local market. Numerous academic studies have found evidence that banks in

concentrated markets (MSAs or rural counties) behave uncompetitively. High level of concentration

have been found to be associated with low deposit rates (Berger and Hannan, 1989; Heitfield and

Prager, 2004), deposit rates which are less responsive to interest rates (Hannan and Berger, 1991),

high loan rates (Hannan, 1991), and low efficiency (Berger and Hannan, 1998).

   The effects of bank competition have also been shown to extend beyond just the banking system.

Within the US, the increase in banking competition following the removal of branching restrictions

was found to increase growth by improving the quality of lending (Jayaratne and Strahan, 1996),

decreasing loan rates (Jayaratne and Strahan, 1998), and decreasing financial barriers to firm entry

(Cetorelli and Strahan, 2006). Cross country evidence also suggests that banking competition is

important. Restrictions on the entry of foreign banks have been found to increase the likelihood

of a banking crisis (Barth et al., 2004), while nationwide concentration in assets has been found to

increase firm financing obstacles in developing countries (Beck et al., 2004).



                                                   87
   This evidence that bank competition is important, and that banks in concentrated markets

behave uncompetitively, supports US competition policy regarding bank mergers. When evaluating

a potential merger between two banks, the key approach to assessing the likely effect on competition

is to look at the effect on the MSA level deposit Herfindahl. Typically, if the merger leaves the

Herfindahl for an MSA under .18 or doesn’t raise the Herfindahl by over .02, then the Federal

Reserve board will not look an further (ABA, 2006).4

   Despite this emphasis on leaving markets unconcentrated, the removal of restrictions on within

state bank branching between 1976 and 1994 and cross-state branching after 1994 have dramatically

changed the structure of the market. Whereas in 1980 there were 14,434 FDIC-Inusured commercial

banks, by 2012 there were only 6,096.5 However, during this time period, the number of offices

increased from 53,172 to 89,805 as larger banks took advantage of the ability to expand into new

markets. This simultaneous decline in the number of institutions and increase in the geographic

spread of these institutions makes how one defines a banking market of critical importance in de-

termining the probable competitive impacts of this consolidation. The exit of small banks makes

concentration at more aggregate levels rise, while the geographic expansion of the branch network

of the remaining banks may have the opposite effect on concentration measured at a finer level.


3.2.2     Importance of Proximity in Banking

Although the MSA level Herfindahl is effective at predicting bank behavior, it is still an open question

whether or not this market definition is the appropriate one for measuring bank concentration. A

second strand of the banking literature has studied the importance of proximity in banking, and

found banking to be very local. Due to transportation costs and the existence of local knowledge,

nearby banks will have an advantage relative to distant banks. This may result in banks achieving

market power depending on the availability of other banks in close proximity.

   Kwast et al. (1997) and Brevoort and Wolken (2009) use survey data to document that individual

financial services and small business lending disproportionately occur in branches of banks within a

few miles of their customers. Brevoort and Hannan (2006) use disclosure data from the Community

Reinvestment Act to study the location of small business lending. They find that the probability of

a bank lending to a tract falls rapidly as the distance between the tract and the nearest branch of

a bank grows.
   4 As a point of reference, a market where 4 banks held 20% of the deposits each, and two banks held 10% of the

deposits each, would have a Herfindahl of .18. If the two smaller banks merged, this would increase the Herfindahl
by .02.
   5 http://www2.fdic.gov/hsob/HSOBRpt.asp




                                                       88
    Figure 1 demonstrates the Brevoort and Hannan (2006) findings graphically. We see that the

probability of an institution making a loan to a particular tract is declining rapidly in the distance

from the tract centroid to the nearest branch of the institution. Although the levels shift for different

years, the slope seems to change little, suggesting that distance is not becoming less important.

Overall, the probability of a bank making a loan to a tract declines from over 80% if the bank is

very close, to about 30% if the bank is 5 kms away, and the rate of decline slows down thereafter.6

    There is also evidence of spatial price discrimination, suggesting that these lending patterns

reflect actual spatial frictions instead of merely being an equilibrium outcome. Degryse and Ongena

(2005) and Agarwal and Hauswald (2010) show that loan rates for a particular bank vary based

on proximity of the borrower to the bank, as well as the proximity of the borrower to the nearest

competitor. Although the former attributes the findings to transportation costs and the latter

location specific soft information, both papers suggest that distant banks may be a poor substitute

for near banks.


3.2.3      Implications for Bank Market Definition

In short, the research on distance and lending has consistently found that proximity to depository

institutions remains highly relevant to the majority of individuals and small firms. These customers

almost exclusively use banks within a few miles of them and are subject to price discrimination

based on their location. Transportation costs and asymmetric access to soft information over space

make it so that distant banks are often not viable substitutes for local banks. The finding that there

are significant difficulties to lending at a distance raises questions regarding the appropriateness of

the MSA level market definition.

    To see how the MSA level concentration measure could be problematic, consider the two stylized

banking markets presented in Figure 2. In the left figure, each institution locates in one neighbor-

hood, in the right, each institution is evenly spread across neighborhoods. These markets will have

the same concentration as measured by the MSA Herfindahl, as this measure only depends on the

total market share of each institution without regard to the location of their branches. However, if

people bank predominantly in their own neighborhood, then the competitiveness of the two markets

differ substantially. In one case, every bank has a local monopoly, in the other, every bank has three

competitors wherever it operates.
   6 This probably understates the true effect of distance. For one, there is measurement error in distance due to

occasional geocoding errors and due to the fact that I measure distance to centroids instead of actual borrower
locations. These errors will tend to attenuate the observed relationship between lending and distance. Secondly, only
large banks need to report. These large banks are more prone to rely on hard information than engage in proximity
dependent relationship lending, making distance more of a deterrent for the small local banks which don’t report.


                                                         89
    Although the allocation of branches in Figure 2a is highly stylized, it still may be relevant. Take

for example banking laws in Illinois in the early 90s: banks could have up to five branches, two

could be out of county so long as they were within ten miles of the home office (Rice and Davis,

2007). Even this was a liberalization as previously the only branching allowed was a drive up facility

within 1500 feet of the loan office. Furthermore, banks had one mile of “home office protection”

prohibiting other banks from operating within one mile of their home bank without their permission.

This restriction to branching only locally and protection from outside entry could easily produce the

type of market structure shown in Figure 2a. Although such restrictions have since been removed,

opening a new branch is costly enough that the effects on market structure could persist. As a

result, firms or individuals in a market deemed competitive by the conventional metric could still

contend with having limited banking options within their area.



3.3       Local Concentration Measure

3.3.1      Index Definition

If distance creates obstacles for lending or imposes costs on bank customers, then market level

concentration measures can be misleading. In this case, the level of concentration relevant to a firm

or individual could be the concentration of banks within a certain radius of their location. This is

what I measure.

    In order to construct this more local measure of concentration, I use the ARCGIS10 North

American Address Locater to geocode the location of each bank branch in the US from 1994 to

2012. Branch addresses and deposits come from the FDIC’s Summary of Deposits (SOD), an annual

survey of branch offices for all FDIC-insured institutions. It includes commercial banks, thrifts, and

US branches of foreign banks.

    I then calculate the deposit Herfindahl for each census tract, using the set of branches within

a certain distance of the tract centroid. Denote sb,d,c the portion of the total deposits in branches

within d kilometers of the centroid of census tract c which are held by institution b ∈ B.7 Then the

tract level herfindahl for the distance parameter would be:

                                                                X
                                             HHI tractdc =            s2bdc                                      (3.1)
                                                                b∈B

    7 For example, suppose there are three branches within 2km of tract c: 2 for bank of America and 1 for Wells Fargo.

If the branches have equal deposits, then sBA,2,c = 32 and sW F,2,c = 13 , and thus the Tract Herfindahl would be 95 .




                                                          90
My measure of concentration for market m is then the average tract Herfindahl of census tracts in

the market. Denoting Cm the set of census tracts in market m, my measure of concentration is:

                                                   1 X X 2
                                  HHI locdm =           sbdc                                      (3.2)
                                                 |Cm |
                                                       c∈Cm b∈B


Consider again the market structure hypothesized in Figure 2 and assume each bank holds equal

deposits. While the conventional Herfindahl would treat the two markets as equally concentrated

at 14 , the Local Herfinadahl would take into account the segmentation within the markets and thus

differ. Where every bank had an equal share in each market in panel (b), the local Herfindahl would

remain 14 , however, where every bank had a local monopoly, the local Herfindahl would be 1.


3.3.2    How Do Local and MSA Concentration Differ?

If local concentration is indeed a better indicator for competition, how well does the conventional

measure capture this? Figure 3 provides scatter plots for the MSA Herfindahl and the Local Herfind-

ahl for various distance parameters. The left panel is for the year 1994 and the right 2012. Of the

most interest are the leftmost columns which have the MSA Herfindahl on the x axis and the Local

Herfindahl at a particular distance on the y axis. Although the MSA and the local concentration

measures are strongly positively correlated, the relationship is far from perfect, especially for finer

distance measures. The bottom panel shows how the correlation of the Local Herfindahl with the

MSA Herfindahl varies by the distance parameter. For the year 2012, the correlation is around .2 at

a distance of 2 kms, and rises to around .8 at 16 kms. The key take away is that if banks compete

over only a small area, the MSA Herfindahl may be a poor proxy for the competitiveness of the local

banking sector.

   Another question is how concentration changed following the allowance for interstate branching.

The ability of large banks to expand and take over small banks could result in increases in concen-

tration. However, the removal of entry restrictions could also allow these banks enter areas which

previously had limited banking options. Figure 4 plots average values (weighted by the 2010 popu-

lation) for the MSA Herfindahl and the Local Herfindahl at various parameters for the years 1994

to 2012. Although conventionally measured MSA concentration rises drastically from .105 to .146,

concentration when measured at a more local level is actually declining over time. This suggests

that although larger banks may be expanding their market share and taking over small local banks,

they are increasingly competing over a wider area within each market and thus possibly making

each locality more competitive.

                                                  91
    To understand what it means for more aggregate concentration to be rising, and local concen-

tration falling, note that the Local Herfindahl can be decomposed into a term relating to the MSA

concentration and a term relating to the variance of banks’ market shares across the sub-markets:

                                                         X                     X
                                        HHI locdm =             var(sb ) +           s¯2b                          (3.3)
                                                         b∈B                   b∈B


                       1                                          1
                                                 
                                    (sbc − s¯b )2 , and s¯b =
                              P                                          P
Where var(sb ) =     |Cm |                                      |Cm |          sbc . The second term is nearly identical
                             c∈Cm                                       c∈Cm
to the MSA Herfindahl. Thus to have MSA concentration rising, but local concentration falling,

means that the variance of market shares is falling faster than aggregate concentration has been

rising. Namely, banks are competing more widely within markets, causing deposits in a particular

bank to be spread more evenly throughout MSAs instead of concentrated in one area.



3.4        Local Market Structure and Bank Performance

3.4.1      Data & Methodology

Local and MSA concentration are thus different, but which better reflects the competitiveness of

the banking market? In this section, I demonstrate that the Local Herfindahl and Tract Herfindahl

better relate to variables pertaining to bank pricing or profitability. Namely, the location pattern of

the banks within the market impacts the competitiveness, not just aggregate market shares.

    I use balance sheet data for US banks from the Consolidated Report of Condition and Income

(Call Report) to assess how concentration in a bank’s markets impacts their decisions and perfor-

mance. The variables computed from the Call Reports frequently have a few extreme outliers, most

likely due to reporting errors or small denominators, so I drop the lowest and highest 1% of the ob-

servations for each variable every year. I also drop any institutions which merged with or acquired

another institution in a given year.

    I don’t have branch level data, so I can’t assess, for example, how Bank of America behaves

in concentrated versus unconcentrated markets. Instead, I use the geocoded branch locations to

calculate the deposit weighted average concentration in the markets (MSA or Rural County) or

tracts that the bank locates in.8 If a bank i has a set of branches j ∈ Ji , with Dj,i,c,m,t denoting

the deposits in branch j, tract c, market m and year t, then the relevant measures of concentration

will be:
   8 Over half of the institutions hold deposits in only one market, and about 95% have a single market accounting

for over 50% of their deposits. Results are robust to using concentration in the largest market as the institution level
measure of exposure to concentration


                                                           92
                                                1 X
                              HHI mkti,t =          Dj,i,c,m,t HHI mktm,t
                                               Di,t
                                                     j∈Ji

                                                1 X
                               HHI locdi,t =        Dj,i,c,m,t HHI locdm,t
                                               Di,t
                                                     j∈Ji

                                                 1 X
                             HHI tractdi,t =         Dj,i,c,m,t HHI tractdc,t
                                                Di,t
                                                     j∈Ji

   Where Di,t is aggregate deposits for bank i in year t. Thus I have three bank specific measures

of concentration: market concentration reflecting the availability of competitors within the MSA or

county, local concentration reflecting the availability of competitors in the MSA or county as well

as the degree to which those banks geographically segment the market, and tract concentration,

reflecting the availability of competitors in the areas directly surrounding a bank’s branches. I then

run regressions to assess which concentration measure impacts bank decision variables:



                              yi,t = α + β 0 HHIi,t−1 + γ 0 Xi,t + δt + ηi + i,t                          (3.4)


   Where yi,t is the institution level outcome variable from the Call Reports data relating to either

bank pricing or profitability. δt and ηi are year and institution fixed effects respectively. HHIi,t−1

is a vector of variables relating to the institution’s exposure to concentration, and Xi,t is a set of

controls.9 Standard errors are clustered by bank.

   If the relevant market is the more aggregate one, as assumed by most the previous literature, then

one would expect the conventional market Herfindahl to be significant, and the others insignificant

after controlling for the conventional measure. In this situation, tract concentration would be subject

to measurement error due to the fact that it excludes far off banks which are in fact relevant. Local

concentration would be subject to measurement error as the component of the measure relating to

the spread of the institutions within the market would just be adding noise to the proper measure.

   However, if the relevant market is highly local, we get different predictions. In this case, it is more

important to have competing banks in the near area than in the MSA. The conventional Herfindahl

would be flawed as it identifies an area as competitive if there is low concentration at a highly

aggregate level, even if individual banks are able to dominate smaller segments of the market. The

Local Herfindahl would account for this segmentation and should thus better predict bank markups.

The Tract Herfindahl directly measures the concentration in the area around the bank’s branches,
   9X
      i,t includes log total deposits, log number of branches, share of market deposits in banks headquartered in
another state, and the bank’s market share in its largest market. None of the estimates are very sensitive to the
control set, so it is emphasized little throughout the rest of the paper.


                                                       93
and should thus also predict markups better than the conventional Herfindahl. Generally, the data

support the claim that local concentration is what matters.


3.4.2     Effects of 6km Local Concentration

Lending Rates Table 1 shows the relationship between concentration and lending rates. In
                                                                                                  loan income 10
Columns 1-3, the dependent variable is the average rate charged for lending: 100 ×                   loans   .

If higher concentration results in greater market power, then this should allow banks to charge

borrowers higher interest rates.

   Column 1, suggests that this is indeed the case. The coefficient implies that a one standard

deviation increase in market concentration raises the lending rate by about 3 basis points, which

is economically small but statistically significant at the 1% level. When local concentration is

included in a horse race regression in Column 2, the coefficient on the conventional Herfindahl falls

by almost 75% and becomes insignificant while local concentration is significant at the 1% level. Even

controlling for the conventional Herfindahl, a one standard deviation increase in the local Herfindahl

raises the lending rate by about 9 basis points. Column 3 additionally includes the concentration in

the 6km neighborhood surrounding the bank branches, which is significant at the 1% level with a

one standard deviation increase raising the average lending rate by 6 basis points, after controlling

for the market level concentration measures. The local concentration measure remains significant at

the 5% level and larger in magnitude than the conventional Herfindahl.

   This measure of lending rates can be problematic as not all lending is likely to be sensitive to

local market structure. For example, mortgage lending is less sensitive to the common information

problems from lending at a distance due to the fact that the loans are collateralized and easily sold

on the secondary market.

   Next I look at the rate charged on commercial and industrial loans. If a bank is close to a firm, it

may reduce the costs of monitoring and thus help the bank overcome some of the agency problems

associated with debt finance. Proximity may be particularly important for small businesses for

whom hard information such as a history of financial statements is unavailable. If soft information

is proximity dependent, then it may be that only banks close to a business are willing to lend.

This would make the distinction between market concentration and local concentration particularly

important for commercial lending.

   In Columns 4-6, the dependent variable is the average interest rate charged on commercial and
  10 Income and expenditure measures like loan income and deposit interest are totals for the calendar year, while

stock variables like loans and deposits are the average of the first and fourth quarter reported value.



                                                       94
industrial loans (business loans not secured by real estate). In Column 4, we see that the magnitude

of the effect of conventionally measured concentration is higher by about a third compared to

when average loan rate was the dependent variable, although it is insignificant.11 Adding local

concentration in Column 5 causes the coefficient to become virtually zero. A one standard deviation

increase in local concentration, controlling for market concentration, is found to raise commercial

and industrial lending rates by 20 basis points, although it is only significant at the 10% level. The

most dramatic effect is seen for the concentration in the 6kms surrounding a bank’s branches. A

one standard deviation increase in the tract concentration, holding market and local concentration

constant, raises the lending rates by 17 basis points. The coefficient on local concentration falls by

almost 60% and becomes insignificant while, conventionally measured concentration remains near 0.


Deposit Rates         How are depositors are impacted? Table 2 shows that the increased returns on

loans in concentrated markets are not passed on to depositors. In Columns 1-3, the independent
                                                          interest on deposits
variable is the interest rate on deposits: 100 ×                deposits       ,   in Columns 4-6 it is the service
                                     service charges on deposits
charge rate on deposits: 100 ×                 deposits          .

    In Column 1, we see that higher conventional concentration is associated with lower rates offered

on deposits. A one standard deviation increase lowers the average deposit rate by 2.5 basis points,

and is significant at the 1% level. Controlling for local concentration causes the coefficient to fall

by almost half, while local concentration is significant at the 1% level. A one standard deviation

increase in local concentration lowers the deposit rate by 4.5 basis points. Tract concentration in

Column 6 is insignificant.

    The distinction between local and MSA concentration is less significant for deposit rates than

for other variables. This could be attributed to deposit insurance ensuring that deposit accounts are

roughly homogeneous, thus removing any room for local information to be relevant. Alternatively,

since ATMs are not counted as bank branches, the geographic spread of branches may not reflect

access to bank services as well as for loans, where the interactions are with loan officers located in

a bank branch.

    Columns 4-6 show that local concentration not only results in lower interest payments to deposi-

tors, but also results in depositors needing to pay more in service charges. Conventionally measured

concentration in Column 4 is unrelated to the service charge rate, however local concentration is

found to increase the service charge rate and is significant at the 1% level. When the 6km concentra-
  11 Until 2001, only larger banks had to report how much income was derived from commercial and industrial loans.

The lack of significance is likely attributable to the greater weight place on crisis years, and on larger banks who are
less sensitive to local market structure



                                                          95
tion is added, it is also significant at the 1% level in the same direction, while the local concentration

measure remains significant at the 1% level.


Profits   Finally, Table 3 demonstrates that the increased interest margins translates into higher
                                                                                              N et Income
profits. In the first three columns, profits are measured by the return on equity: 100 ×         Equity   ,
                                                                          N et Income
in the second three it is measured as the Net Profit Margin: 100 ×          Income .    Qualitatively the

results are similar for either measure of profitability. Banks in more concentrated markets earn

higher profits, with market concentration being significant at the 5 or 10% level. Including local

concentration makes market concentration insignificant, while the predicted impact of a 1 standard

deviation increase in concentration is about 4 times as large as with the conventional concentration

measure. Tract concentration is insignificant.

   Overall, these results provide support for the idea that the local market structure impacts bank

performance. In concentrated markets, banks charge higher interest rates, offer lower deposit rates,

have higher service charges, and earn higher profits. These effects are uniformly larger in magni-

tude and significance when local concentration is used instead of market concentration. Market

concentration only remains significant in the horse race regression for deposit rates, even then the

predicted impact is greatly diminished. This is all consistent with local concentration being the

superior measure of market power, and raises the possibility that previous failures to support the

structure-conduct performance paradigm were due to attenuation bias stemming from the mismea-

surement of market power.


3.4.3     Effects by Distance Parameter

For which distance parameter does concentration best relates to bank markups? The results thus

far with the 6km distance parameter suggest that market structure at a finer level than the MSA

determines the competitive pressures faced by banks, but they do not answer the question of how

fine a measure is needed. Here I assess the proper geographic extent of bank markets by testing

which distance best relates to bank markups.

   This exercise is particularly important in light of the findings in Figure 4, which shows that while

concentration at the MSA level has been rising over time, concentration at a finer level has been

falling. On average, there are more banks available within 4km than in the past, but fewer banks

available within 10km. This makes the presumed competitive effects of the recent consolidation

depend critically on the proper market definition. If concentration for higher parameter values is

found to matter, then the recent consolidation is likely to have harmed competition. If instead lower

                                                   96
parameters are found to be more predictive, then the decline in highly local concentration would

suggest that the diminished tendency of banks to segment the market would more than make up for

the increase in concentration at more aggregated levels.

   Figure 5 shows how the findings for the relationship between concentration and lending rates

vary by distance parameter. Each point represents the result of a horse race regression following

the specification in equation 3. The left panel includes the conventional Herfindahl and the Local

Herfindahl for a particular distance parameter. The distance parameter is given on the X-axis, with

a value of 0 being the regression with just the conventional Herfindahl. The solid black line gives the

coefficient for the Local Herfindal, and the dashed line the 95% confidence interval. The light gray

line is the coefficient on the conventional Herfindahl. To facilitate comparison, all the concentration

measures are standardized, so the value on the y-axis can be interpreted as the percentage point

increase in lending rates from increasing concentration by one standard deviation.

   The coefficient on local concentration is maximized when the distance parameter is 4 kms. Here

a one standard deviation increase in local concentration is found to raise the lending rate by about

10 basis points, compared to about 1 basis point for the conventional Herfindahl. The coefficient for

local concentration declines monotonically as the distance parameter increases after 4.

   The right panel presents the same analysis as the left, except it uses the concentration around

the institution’s actual branches instead of average local concentration in the markets where the

institution has branches. For every distance, tract concentration is significant at at least the 5%

level and larger than the coefficient on the conventional Herfindahl. The maximum occurs at a

distance of 8km, with a coefficient just under .075.

   Figure 6 does the same for the commercial and industrial loan rate. The pattern with the local

Herfindahl in the left panel is comparable to before. The coefficient is maximized at 4kms, mostly

declines thereafter, and the effect of local concentration is found to be higher than for conventional

concentration so long as the distance parameter is less than 12km. The magnitude of the effect is

much higher than before, with the coefficient taking a maximum value around .25 as opposed to .1,

but it is much less precisely estimated, with the effect only being statistically significant from 0 at

the 5% level for the distance parameter of 4kms.

   The right panel has a clearer message. The coefficient for tract concentration is maximized

at 8km, and declines linearly for smaller or larger coefficients. A one standard deviation increase

in concentration in the 8km around a bank’s branches raises the rate charged on commercial and

industrial loans by over 25 basis points, with the coefficient on conventionally measured concentration

essentially being 0. Increasing or decreasing the distance parameter by 4km, cuts the predicted

                                                  97
impact by almost half. Namely it is the banks within 5 miles that account for the competitiveness

of a bank’s commercial lending rates, and when this concentration is controlled for, conventional

concentration has no explanatory power.



3.5        Local Concentration and Young Firm Finance

3.5.1       Background

One direction where an improved measure of banking concentration could yield substantial gains

is in the study of how bank market structure impacts the allocation of credit. Whether bank

market power is beneficial or harmful to the ability of young firms to obtain finance is theoretically

ambiguous while empirical work has been inconclusive.

   The findings of the last section support the claim that local concentration provides banks with

market power, however the aggregate implications of this market power regarding the allocation of

credit are not straight forward. One school of thought is that concentration is beneficial for young

firms. Petersen and Rajan (1995) argue that banks may lend to young firms at subsidized rates

because they can extract rents in the future. In competitive markets without the same potential for

future capture, banks may be unwilling to lend to young, informationally difficult, firms profitably.

Using data from the Survey of Small Business Finance, they demonstrate that in concentrated

markets (measured as the deposit Herfindahl for the MSA or rural county), younger firms are

charged lower interest rates and receive more credit. Similarly, Cetorelli and Gambera (2001) find

that bank concentration promotes the growth of financially dependent sectors by improving credit

access to young firms, despite exerting a negative effect on growth overall.12 Seeing as young firms

are a significant driver of job creation (Haltiwanger et al., 2013), this raises the question of whether

the greater market power is actually a problem.

   However, there are good reasons to think that young firms would be especially harmed by con-

centration. Young firms may struggle to obtain non-bank external finance due to their opaqueness or

their size making the fixed costs of securities issuances problematic. Furthermore, young firms may

struggle to self finance due to not having had sufficient time to accumulate earnings. This is further

amplified if young firms face start up costs resulting in low initial profitability. Consistent with this,

Cetorelli and Strahan (2006) shows that MSA concentration has a negative effect on business entry

while Beck et al. (2004) and Chong et al. (2013) find that concentration is associated with greater
 12 See   Fischer (2000) and Zarutskie (2003) for more evidence in support of the information hypothesis




                                                         98
financial constraints for small businesses.


3.5.2      Methodology

On top of the difficulties measuring banking concentration, determining the extent to which firms

are financially constrained is problematic. First, one can not simply run growth regressions with

concentration as an explanatory variable as high growth for young firms could either be attributed to

a lack of financial constraints fueling capital accumulation, or to the existence of financing constraints

forcing firms to enter at an inefficiently small scale then grow fast with the use of retained earnings.13

Second, comparing the age or size distribution of firms in concentrated and unconcentrated markets

is problematic as the entry of new firms could allow more banks to profitably operate, creating

concerns over the direction of causality. Finally, firm level measures of constraints tend to only be

available for publicly listed firms who are less financially constrained and less bank dependent.

    In this section I test how well firms in an MSA are able to expand following a demand shock.

With perfect capital markets, firms should face an elastic capital supply curve and thus be able to

increase their scale substantially when it is profitable to do so. However, if firms are financially

constrained, investing more than can be financed with their own cash flows may be prohibitively

costly. If labor and capital are complements, this diminished sensitivity of capital to demand due

to financial frictions will result in a similarly diminished sensitivity of employment to demand.

If firms use finance to hire labor, the effects can be even more dramatic, with financial frictions

directly inhibiting employment expansion instead of operating indirectly through capital. Either

way, financially constrained firms will increase labor less in response to a positive.

    Specifically, I instead investigate how the elasticity of local employment growth with respect to

the national growth in the local industries varies by bank market structure.14 An increase in national

employment in a given industry is likely to reflect some sort of national shock to productivity, demand

or expectations, increasing the return to investment in areas with employment in the industry, but

unrelated local financial markets. In the appendix, I show that this elasticity is a decreasing function

of the elasticity of the marginal cost of capital with respect to capital of the firms in the city.

    Figure 7 provides the graphical intuition for the relationship between financial frictions and the

response to demand shocks. Consider, a firm with a downward sloping capital demand curve for

capital. For a given shift in demand, the output response will depend on the shape of the loan offer
  13 Kerr and Nanda (2010) show that following an increase in competition due to branch deregulation, firms entered

closer to their maximum size.
  14 This exercise is similar in spirit to Wurgler (2000), which demonstrates that countries with a larger financial

sector allocate more investment to growing industries and less to declining industries.



                                                        99
function. If there is premium for external finance as in Gerali et al. (2010) or C´
                                                                                  urdia and Woodford

(2010), then firms for whom the marginal product of capital is within the interest rate wedge would

not adjust their capital stock. Since high local concentration is found to be associated with higher

rates on commercial loans, this means that there is a wider range of productivities such that firms

would be unwilling to borrow in response to a demand shock. These firms will have capital growth

determined by cash flows and thus be less synchronized with national employment growth. If firms

have leverage constraints as in Buera and Shin (2013) or Moll (2014), then productive firms will

be unable to borrow to fund expansion up to the point where the marginal product of capital is

equal to the interest rate. Again constrained firms will have growth depend on asset growth instead

of productivity growth. Finally, if higher leverage increases expected bankruptcy costs as in costly

state verification model (Townsend, 1979), this would result in an upward sloping marginal cost of

capital curve.


3.5.3    Data and Specification

My strategy is to test for financing constraints by examining how responsive firm growth is to a

shock to the return to investment. I follow Bartik (1991) and use national industry level growth

as a shifter of demand which is exogenous to local conditions. By using exogenous demand shocks,

this methodology overcomes the reverse causality concerns mentioned before. Secondly, by using

aggregated data, I’m able to include small and young firms, who would be more sensitive to bank

competition but, by virtue of not being publicly listed, have little available data.

   The measure of the demand shock is:

                                             I
                                             X
                                shockm,t =         θi,m,t−1 emp growthi,t
                                             i=1


where θi,c,t−1 is the share of private march employment in MSA m in industry i in previous year,

and emp growthi,t is HP-filtered national employment growth in the industry for the year.

   The primary specification used is:


        growthm,t = α + β1 shockm,t + β2 shockm,t × HHIm,t + β3 HHIm,t + δt + ηm + m,t


where growthm,t is MSA level wage or employment growth. HHIm,t is a measure of concentra-

tion, either the conventionally measured MSA concentration, or the 6km local concentration. The

concentration measure is normalized, so the coefficient on shockm,t is the elasticity of local growth


                                                    100
with respect to national growth in an MSA with an average concentration, while the coefficient

on shockm,t × HHIm,t is how much the elasticity falls when concentration rises by one standard

deviation. If concentration is associated with higher financial frictions, this would imply β2 < 0,

so that higher concentration results in a smaller elasticity of MSA growth with respect to national

growth.

   Industry level data comes from the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages (QCEW) for

the years 1990 to 2006 at the three digit 2002 NAICS level. This is used to calculate the national

growth at the industry level, and the employment share at the industry×MSA level to create the

shock variable. It is also used to calculate wage and employment growth at the MSA level. The

QCEW doesn’t include data disaggregated by firm age. I use the Business Dynamic statistics (BDS)

to calculate the annual employment growth rate of young firms and mature firms at the MSA level,

where I define young firms as firms which are 0-5 years old and mature firms as firms which are 6

years or older. A more detailed description of the data is in the appendix.


3.5.4     Findings

Table 4 presents the results without the age breakdown. The first three columns use the 6km

local Herfindahl as the measure of concentration, and the last three use the conventional MSA

level concentration. National growth in the local industry is unsurprisingly strongly with MSA

employment growth. A one percentage point shock results in employment growth of .87 and .96

percentage points for MSAs with an average local and MSA concentration respectively. Of greater

interest is how this elasticity varies across cities. Looking at the coefficient on the interaction term,

we see that cities with a 1 standard deviation higher local Herfinadahl have an elasticity of growth

with respect to the Bartik instrument which .16 percentage points lower. Having a 1 standard

deviation higher conventional concentration lowers the elasticity by .1 percentage points.

   The findings when the QCEW employment growth measure is used is comparable to with the

BDS, with the difference between the effect of local concentration vs MSA concentration being

slightly starker. Unlike the BDS, the QCEW includes wage data, allowing me to check if the

findings are attributable to differences in the elasticity of labor supply. Higher local concentration

results in wages which are less responsive to demand shocks, suggesting that heterogeneity in the

response to demand shocks is attributable to differences in the size of the labor demand shift instead

of differences in the elasticity of labor supply. However, the coefficient is insignificant for local

concentration and even slightly positive for MSA concentration.



                                                  101
   The goal of the section is to show how concentration relates to financial frictions by age group.

Table 5 conducts the analysis for the BDS data broken down by firm age. The first two columns

demonstrate that local concentration is particularly harmful for firms which are five years old or

younger. A one standard deviation increase in local concentration lowers the elasticity of employment

growth with respect to the Bartik instrument by .34 percentage points for young firms but only .12

for mature firms. These effects are .1 and .08 respectively when conventional concentration is used,

with the effect of concentration on young firms becoming insignificant.

   In short, local concentration is found to inhibit growth following a demand shock, particularly for

young firms. This is consistent with the hypothesis that young firms are more reliant on bank finance,

and are thus disproportionately harmed by a low degree of competition. The fact that concentration

is found to inhibit growth for young firms only when the local measure is used, suggests that previous

studies relating concentration to young firm finance may have not been measuring concentration as

is relevant to young firms. Finally, having local concentration matter more for young firms raises

confidence that the channel of influence is actually through bank relationship lending. Young firms

are more bank dependent and informationally opaque, making proximity and the access to soft

information it provides more important. Thus it makes perfect sense that the location patterns of

the banks in an MSA are more important for young than mature firms.



3.6     Conclusion

There has been a debate in the banking literature as to whether the proper extent of a bank

market is the state or something more local, namely the county or MSA. I present evidence that

the proper market is actually even more local than previously suggested. My proposed measure of

concentration, which uses the average concentration of small sub-markets within the conventionally

defined banking markets, consistently outperforms the conventional MSA/county level Herfindahl in

horse race regressions. This suggests that it isn’t enough to have many banks competing in the same

market, instead competitiveness requires banks to locate near competitors as opposed to clustering

and dominating areas within the market. The conventional Herfindahl measure doesn’t account for

the location of branches within markets and thus fails to effectively measure concentration.

   These findings are relevant to merger policy, which frequently use the market Herfindahl to assess

the likely competitive effects of a horizontal merger. In light of the results of this paper, it isn’t

sufficient to look at the change in market shares within the market, but instead one must look at

the locations of the acquiring and acquired branches. If the two banks tend to locate in different


                                                 102
sub-markets, the merger is unlikely to be damaging. However, if the bank branches tend to be close

to one another, the merger is more likely to result in a decline in the competitiveness of the bank

market.

   These findings are also relevant to the academic literature, which frequently uses a market

Herfindahl to measure competition. Studies which use it as a control variable may not be suf-

ficiently controlling for bank market power. Studies which have concentration as the variable of

interest may be understating its effects due to this measurement error. For example, while the

market level Herfindahl isn’t significantly related to the responsiveness of young firms to a demand

shock, the local concentration is strongly related. Consequently, this improvement in the measure-

ment of concentration is important for understanding the effects of bank market structure on the

allocation of credit and growth.

   Finally, these findings are important in the construction of an accurate narrative of the consoli-

dation of the banking sector over the last 20 years. The nearly 40% rise in the MSA Herfindahl after

the onset of interstate branching could be a cause for concern given the existing findings that this

concentration is associated with higher interest margins and barriers to firm entry. However, upon

closer analysis, we see that local concentration is what is associated with a lack of competitiveness

on the part of banks. That concentration at this level is falling should assuage some of the fears

regarding the competitive effects of the consolidation of the banking industry.




                                                103
3.7                          Appendix

3.7.1                        Figures


                                                  Impact of Distance−By Year
               1        .8
   Probability of lending
     .4        .6
               .2




                              0                        5                     10                       15
                                                     Distance to Nearest Branch (kms)

                                                                1997               2001
                                                                2005


                                       Figure 3.1: Declining Probability of Lending Over Distance
Notes: This shows how the probability of a CRA reporting institution making a small business loan in a particular
census tract varies with distance between the tract centroid and the nearest branch of an institution. Probabilities
are determined by local linear regression on the 0-1 loan indicator using an Epanechnikov kernel with a bandwidth of
.2 kilometers. This is done separately for the years 1997, 2001 and 2005.




                                                                  104
                  (a) Locally Concentrated                               (b) Locally Competitive

                                   Figure 3.2: Hypothetical Bank Markets
Notes: This figure presents two hypothetical bank markets. Each letter corresponds to a branch location of a particular
institution. The left figure presents a locally concentrated market, as the branches of each institution cluster in one
part of the market, giving it a local monopoly. The right figure presents a locally competitive market, with the
branches spread evenly throughout and competing with the other institutions in every locality.




                                                         105
                        1994 Concentration Measures                                                   2012 Concentration Measures

                 HHI_msa                                                                          HHI_msa

    .6                                                                               .6
    .4                                                                               .4
                                 HHI_12km                                                                         HHI_12km
    .2                                                                               .2
     0                                                                                0
    .6                                                                               .6
    .4                                                                               .4
                                                     HHI_8km                                                                         HHI_8km
    .2
                                                                                     .2
     0
    .8                                                                               .8
    .6                                                                               .6
                                                                     HHI_4km                                                                        HHI_4km
    .4                                                                               .4
    .2                                                                               .2
         0         .2      .40    .2   .4     .6 0   .2    .4   .6                        0                 .50    .2   .4     .6   .2   .4    .6



                  MSA and Local HHI Correlation, 1994                                              MSA and Local HHI Correlation, 2012
    1




                                                                                     1
    .8




                                                                                     .8
    .6




                                                                                     .6
    .4




                                                                                     .4
    .2




                                                                                     .2
    0




                                                                                     0




             0                    5                       10             15                   0                    5                     10             15
                                            distance                                                                         distance




                                  Figure 3.3: How Similar Are MSA and Local Concentration?
Notes: The top panels present scatter plots for the year 1994 (left) and 2012 (right). The left most column of each
scatter plot has the conventional Herfindahl on the x axis, and the 4, 8, or 12 km local concentration on the y. The
other scatters are of the local concentration measure for different distances. A small number of MSAs with an MSA
concentration above .5 are dropped to help with the display of the points in the more common range of values.

The bottom graphs display the correlation of the local concentration measure with the conventional MSA concentration
measure for different distances. Again 1994 is on the left and 2012 on the right.




                                                                               106
                                                        Concentration Trends
   −.04−.03−.02−.01 0 .01 .02 .03 .04
               Concentration




                                        1995            2000                   2005                 2010
                                                                      Year

                                                           MSA HHI                    16km HHI
                                                           12km HHI                   8km HHI
                                                           4km HHI


                                               Figure 3.4: Different Trends in Concentration
Notes: This figures display the trend in concentration as measured by the 4, 8, 12, and 16km local concentration
and the conventional MSA Herfindahl from 1994 to 2012. Each point gives the 2010 population weighted average
concentration of the all MSAs in the US for a given year. All values are relative to their respective 1994 concentration
level.




                                                                   107
                                             Dependent Variable: Loan Rate




                                                                                       .1
               .15




                                                                                                  .08
                          .1
    Regression Coefficient




                                                                           Regression Coefficient
                                                                                      .06
            .05




                                                                           .04
               0




                                                                                       .02
               −.05




                               0      5              10       15                                        0      5              10       15
                                          Distance (kms)                                                           Distance (kms)

                                   Local HHI               MSA HHI                                          Tract HHI               MSA HHI
                                   Local 95% CI                                                             Tract 95% CI




                                            Figure 3.5: Impact of Concentration on Loan Rates
Notes: Each point reports coefficients from regressions of the form :Loan rate = α + βConcentrationi,t + γXi,t +
δt + ηi + i,t . In the left panel Concentrationi,t includes conventional concentration and local concentration, in the
right it includes conventional concentration and tract concentration. The distance parameter is given on the x-axis,
with a value of 0 being the specification where only conventional concentration is included. Concentration measures
are standardized to having a standard deviation of 1. Standard errors are clustered by bank.




                                                                     108
                         Dependent Variable: Commercial & Industrial Loan rate
               .6




                                                                                      .4
                                                                                      .3
                           .4
    Regression Coefficient




                                                                            Regression Coefficient
                                                                                          .2
             .2




                                                                                .1
               0




                                                                                      0
               −.2




                                                                                      −.1




                                0      5              10       15                                    0      5              10       15
                                           Distance (kms)                                                       Distance (kms)

                                    Local HHI               MSA HHI                                      Tract HHI               MSA HHI
                                    Local 95% CI                                                         Tract 95% CI




                                    Figure 3.6: Impact of Concentration on Commercial Loan Rates
Notes: Each point reports coefficients from regressions of the form :CI Loan rate = α + βConcentrationi,t + γXi,t +
δt + ηi + i,t . In the left panel Concentrationi,t includes conventional concentration and local concentration, in the
right it includes conventional concentration and tract concentration. The distance parameter is given on the x-axis,
with a value of 0 being the specification where only conventional concentration is included. Concentration measures
are standardized to having a standard deviation of 1. Standard errors are clustered by bank.




                                                                      109
                    Figure 3.7: Financial Constraints and Response to Demand Shocks

M C Capital                               M C Capital                                  M C Capital
                                                            Supply


                                                                                                               Supply



                            Supply
  rext




                          Demand                                        Demand                                   Demand
  rint                                     rint                                         rint

                                Capital                                      Capital                                     Capital
                assets                                     λ × assets                                assets

         (a) External Mark-up                     (b) Leverage Constraint                      (c) Costly Verification
Notes: Each figure shows an example of how financial constraints would make a firm’s growth less responsive to a
demand shock. If there is a premium to external finance as in (a), there is a wedge between the cost of internal funds
and external funds creating a range of productivities such that a firm will not increase capital when it becomes more
productive. In (b), there is a leverage constraint, so that firms above a certain level of productivity will grow only
when assets grow, not when demand grows. In (c), there is an upward sloping loan offer curve reflecting a greater
probability of default at higher leverage. As the curve gets steeper, expansion becomes more costly and firms will
respond less to changes in demand.




                                                           110
3.7.2      Tables

                        Table 3.1: Impact of Concentration on Loan Rates

                                          Loan Rates                                    CI-Loan Rates
                              (1)               (2)              (3)             (4)           (5)             (6)
  HHI mkt                  0.249∗∗∗           0.0660           0.0528          0.337         -0.0395         -0.0989
                            (2.80)            (0.69)           (0.55)          (0.95)        (-0.09)         (-0.23)

  HHI loc                                   0.396∗∗∗          0.250∗∗                        0.861∗           0.380
                                             (3.44)            (2.12)                        (1.67)           (0.70)

  HHI tract                                                  0.169∗∗∗                                       0.556∗∗∗
                                                              (3.40)                                         (2.77)
  Observations              136705           136705           136705           76663          76663          76663
  Year FE                    Yes              Yes              Yes              Yes            Yes            Yes
  Bank FE                    Yes              Yes              Yes              Yes            Yes            Yes
  Controls                   Yes              Yes              Yes              Yes            Yes            Yes
  t statistics in parentheses
  * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of the form :yi,t = α + βConcentrationi,t + γXi,t + δt + ηi + i,t .
The dependent variable is the average loan rate in Columns 1-3 and the average loan rate for commercial and industrial
loans in Columns 4-6. In Columns 1 &4, concentration is the average market Herfindahl for the markets in which
the institution holds deposits, weighted by deposits. Columns 2 & 4, add the average 6km local concentration for the
bank. Columns 3 & 6 additionally includes the average deposit concentration of the banks operating within 6km of
tracts where the bank’s branches are located, again weighted by deposits. All specifications cover the years 1994 to
2010 and include year and institution fixed effects and bank controls. Standard errors are clustered by institution.




                                                           111
                      Table 3.2: Impact of Concentration on Deposit Rates

                                     Deposit Rates                                Service Charge Rates
                           (1)               (2)             (3)             (4)            (5)                (6)
 HHI mkt                -0.212∗∗∗         -0.120∗∗        -0.117∗∗        0.00315       -0.0794∗∗∗         -0.0828∗∗∗
                         (-4.05)           (-2.03)         (-1.97)         (0.12)         (-2.77)            (-2.89)

 HHI loc                                 -0.200∗∗∗        -0.166∗∗                        0.178∗∗∗          0.143∗∗∗
                                          (-2.79)          (-2.23)                         (4.64)            (3.67)

 HHI tract                                                 -0.0384                                         0.0408∗∗∗
                                                           (-1.20)                                           (2.73)
 Observations             137196           137196          137196         135829           135829           135829
 Year FE                   Yes              Yes              Yes           Yes              Yes               Yes
 Bank FE                   Yes              Yes              Yes           Yes              Yes               Yes
 Controls                  Yes              Yes              Yes           Yes              Yes               Yes
 t statistics in parentheses
 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of the form :yi,t = α + βConcentrationi,t + γXi,t + δt + ηi + i,t .
The dependent variable is the average rate on deposits columns 1-3 and the average service charge rate in columns
4-6. In columns 1 &4, concentration is the average market Herfindahl for the markets in which the institution holds
deposits, weighted by deposits. Columns 2 & 4, add the average 6km local concentration for the bank. Columns 3
& 6 additionally includes the average deposit concentration of the banks operating within 6km of tracts where the
bank’s branches are located, again weighted by deposits. All specifications cover the years 1994 to 2010 and include
year and institution fixed effects and bank controls. Standard errors are clustered by institution.




                                                           112
                       Table 3.3: Impact of Concentration on Bank Profits

                                   Return on Equity                                 Net Profit Margin
                             (1)            (2)               (3)             (4)             (5)               (6)
  HHI mkt                  1.626∗         -0.374            -0.338          3.348∗∗         -0.924            -0.970
                           (1.68)         (-0.34)           (-0.31)          (2.29)         (-0.55)           (-0.58)
  HHI loc                                4.392∗∗∗          4.722∗∗∗                        9.345∗∗∗          8.904∗∗∗
                                          (3.25)            (3.38)                          (4.36)            (4.10)
  HHI tract                                                 -0.385                                             0.509
                                                            (-0.71)                                           (0.65)
  Observations            137185          137185            137185          137218          137218            137218
  Year FE                  Yes             Yes                Yes            Yes             Yes                Yes
  Bank FE                  Yes             Yes                Yes            Yes             Yes                Yes
  Controls                 Yes             Yes                Yes            Yes             Yes                Yes
  t statistics in parentheses
  * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
Notes: This table reports coefficients from regressions of the form :yi,t = α + βConcentrationi,t + γXi,t + δt + ηi + i,t .
The dependent variable is the return on equity in Columns 1-3 and the profit margin in Columns 4-6. In Columns 1
&4, concentration is the average market Herfindahl for the markets in which the institution holds deposits, weighted
by deposits. Columns 2 & 4, add the average 6km local concentration for the bank. Columns 3 & 6 additionally
includes the average deposit concentration of the banks operating within 6km of tracts where the bank’s branches are
located, again weighted by deposits. All specifications cover the years 1994 to 2010 and include year and institution
fixed effects and bank controls. Standard errors are clustered by institution.




                                                           113
                 Table 3.4: Concentration and Response to Demand Shocks

                        Employment Growth          Wage Growth         Employment Growth           Wage Growth
                         BDS       QCEW              QCEW               BDS      QCEW                QCEW

 Market Definition         6km           6km             6km            MSA            MSA              MSA
                            (1)           (2)             (3)            (4)            (5)              (6)
 shockc,t                0.870∗∗∗      0.720∗∗∗         0.270         0.958∗∗∗       0.791∗∗∗          0.288∗
                          (4.68)        (5.12)          (1.61)         (5.29)         (5.58)           (1.78)

 shockc,t × HHIc,t       -0.162∗∗∗    -0.149∗∗∗        -0.0630        -0.0977∗∗     -0.0631∗∗          0.0140
                          (-3.88)      (-4.88)         (-1.45)         (-2.44)       (-2.44)           (0.42)

 HHIc,t                 0.0000597     -0.00193        -0.000437       -0.000387    -0.00188∗∗∗       -0.00129∗
                          (0.04)       (-1.35)          (-0.21)         (-0.57)       (-2.78)          (-1.66)
 N                         4322         4227             4229            4322          4227             4229
  t statistics in parentheses
  * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
Notes: This table reports regressions of the form growthc,t = α + β1 shockc,t + β2 shockc,t × HHIc,t + β3 HHIc,t +
δt + ηc + i,t . growthc,t is either the growth in employment or payroll per worker for the MSA. shockc,t is the
average growth in national industries, weighted by the share of MSA employment in the industry. HHIc,t is the 6km
local Herfindahl in columns 1-3 and the conventional MSA Herfindahl in columns 4-6, normalized to have a mean of
zero and standard deviation of 1. MSA and year fixed effects are used in each specification, and standard errors are
clustered by MSA.




                                                       114
     Table 3.5: Concentration and Response to Demand Shocks: By Age

                                     Young          Mature           Young          Mature

       Market Definition              6km             6km             MSA             MSA
       shockc,t                     1.265∗∗         0.733∗∗∗        1.422∗∗∗        0.799∗∗∗
                                     (2.45)          (4.15)          (2.70)          (4.65)

       shockc,t × HHIc,t            -0.335∗∗       -0.118∗∗∗        -0.0970        -0.0781∗∗
                                     (-2.57)        (-2.96)         (-0.89)         (-2.18)

       HHIc,t                       -0.00306       -0.000380        -0.00144       -0.000309
                                     (-0.59)         (-0.21)         (-0.72)         (-0.44)
       N                              4287            4322            4287            4322
       t statistics in parentheses
       * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
Notes: This table reports regressions of the form growthc,t = α + β1 shockc,t + β2 shockc,t × HHIc,t +
β3 HHIc,t + δt + ηc + i,t . growthc,t is the growth in employment for age category in the MSA. shockc,t
is the average growth in national industries, weighted by the share of MSA employment in the industry.
HHIc,t is the 6km local Herfindahl in columns 1 & 2 and the conventional MSA Herfindahl in columns 3
&4, normalized to have a mean of zero and standard deviation of 1. MSA and year fixed effects are used
in each specification, and standard errors are clustered by MSA.




                                                  115
3.7.3        Decomposition

One can think of a market as being uncompetitive for two reasons. First, it could be dominated by

a few small firms, enabling tacit collusion with loan or deposit pricing. A second source of a lack of

competitiveness could be that banks tend to concentrate their branches geographically and exhibit

market power in small areas. Conveniently, the local Herfindahl can be simply decomposed into a

component relating to the market level concentration and a component relating to within institution

clustering. After some algebra15 , the local Herfindahl can be written as:

                                                     B
                                                     X                   B
                                                                         X
                                                           var(sb ) +          s¯2b
                                                     b=1                 b=1


                                T                                       T
                            1                                       1
                                                   
                                      (sbt − s¯b )2 , and s¯b =
                                P                                       P
      Where var(sb ) =      T                                       T         sbt . The first part of this expression can be
                                t=1                                     t=1
seen as a measure of the degree to which branches of an institution cluster around other branches

of the institution. A high variance of local deposit shares mean that there are some areas where the

banks hold a very large portion of deposits, and some where they hold very little. Even if a market

is unconcentrated, if the institutions within it dominate the areas in which they operate, then each

locality may be uncompetitive. Lower variance means that banks are more evenly spread across the

market.
                                                       B
                                                            s¯2b , is similar to the conventional Herfindahl16 . The
                                                       P
      The second part of this expression,
                                                      b=1
difference is that instead of sb being measured as the share of deposits in the market held by bank

b, s¯b is the average share held by bank b across the different sub-markets. These measures of market

share differ for two reasons. First, increasing deposits in an area increase measured MSA market

share more than it raises s¯ if there are already a lot of deposits in that area as the denominator

(total deposits) is larger in that region. Second, there may be double counting as deposits in a bank

included in the intersection of multiple localities will be adding deposits to several markets.
 15

                                                        T   B
                                                     1 XX 2
                                       HHIlocal =             s
                                                     T t=1 b=1 bt
                                                       T  B
                                                    1 XX
                                                               (sbt − s¯b )2 + 2sbt s¯b − s¯2b
                                                                                               
                                                 =
                                                   T t=1 b=1
                                                    B       T
                                                       "                              #
                                                   X     1 X
                                                                 (sbt − s¯b )2 + s¯2b
                                                                              
                                                 =
                                                   b=1
                                                         T t=1

 16 It   has a correlation coefficient over .7




                                                               116
3.7.4            Theory

Suppose that production utilizes technology z and inputs capital k and labor l to produce output

according to the function f (z, k, l). Where f has positive first derivatives, positive cross derivatives

and negative second derivatives. Firms hire labor in a competitive market at cost w. However, due

to financial frictions they face a weakly increasing marginal cost of capital curve c(k, a) where ck ≥ 0

and a indexes borrowing costs so that ca ≤ 0.17 The first order conditions of this maximization

problem implicitly determine the factor demands:


                                                      fl (z, k, l) = w =⇒ l? (z, k, w)


                                                    fk (z, k, l) = c(k, a) =⇒ k ? (z, l, a)

                       ∂l? x                  ∂k? x
Letting ηl,x ≡         ∂x l? ,    ηk,x ≡      ∂x k? denote      the elasticity of demand for labor with respect to variable
                   ∂x 1
       ˆ≡
x, and x           ∂t x   denote the growth rate of x, we can calculate the growth rate of labor18 :


                                                          ˆl = ηl,z zˆ + ηl,k kˆ + ηl,w w
                                                                                        ˆ


                                                          kˆ = ηk,z zˆ + ηk,l ˆl + ηk,a a
                                                                                        ˆ


       Combining these equations gives an individual firm’s growth rate:


                                       ˆl =        1
                                                            [(ηl,z + ηl,k ηk,z )ˆ
                                                                                z + ηl,k ηk,a a
                                                                                              ˆ + ηl,w w]
                                                                                                       ˆ
                                              1 − ηl,k ηk,l

For brevity, write this as:
                                                            ˆl = β z zˆ + β a a
                                                                              ˆ + βw w
                                                                                     ˆ


The growth in employment in industry i in city c will come from integrating over the firms growth

within the industry city:
                                                                       Z
                                                          ˆli,c,t =        ˆl(ω)gi,c,t (ω)dω
                                                                       Ω

where ω is the firm type, and gi,c,t (ω) the density of employment of the firm type. Assume that pro-
  17 If a is taken to be assets, this can be seen as a reduced form version of a costly state verification model where

an increase in capital relative to a firm’s assets raises the default probability and thus the cost of external finance.
Alternatively as a firm grows larger, they may be more able to pay the fixed costs of issuing securities lowering the
cost of capital.
  18 By the implicit function theorem and the assumptions on the production function: η              fl,z z
                                                                                             l,z = − f    l?
                                                                                                             > 0, ηl,k =
                                                                                                                              l,l
  f        k                  1   w                       fk,z    z                       fl,k    l                     ca     c
− fl,k     ?   > 0, ηl,w =   fl,l l?
                                       < 0, ηk,z = − f             ?   > 0, ηk,l = − f             ?   > 0, ηk,a =   fk,k −ck k?
                                                                                                                                    >0
      l,l l                                              k,k −ck k                       k,k −ck k




                                                                           117
ductivity growth depends on an industry level shock zˆi,t and idiosyncratic noise which is integrated

                                    ˆi,c,t be determined at the industry×city×year level19 Finally,
out in aggregation. Let wage growth w

assume an elasticity of labor supply ψi,c,t , so that ˆlc,t = ψi,c,t w
                                                                     ˆc,t .

      Under these assumptions, industry MSA employment growth will be:

                                                                             Z
                             ˆli,c,t =       ψi,c,t
                                                          [β¯i,c,t
                                                             z
                                                                   zˆi,t +         β a (ω)ˆ
                                                                                          a(ω)gi,c,t (ω)dω]
                                         ψi,c,t − β¯i,c,t
                                                    w
                                                                             Ω


       x
                      β x (ω)gi,c,t (ω)dω, x ∈ {w, z} is the average sensitivity of employment growth to
                  R
Where βi,c,t ≡
                  Ω
factor x.

      MCA employment growth will then be:

                                           X                               X
                                 ˆlc,t =          θi,c,t ˆli,c,t = β¯c,t
                                                                     z
                                                                                 θi,c,t zˆi,t + Ec,t (β a a
                                                                                                          ˆ)
                                            i∈I                            i∈I


                                                                                                            θi,c,t zˆi,t         ψi,c,t
where θi,c,t denotes the share of employment in industry i, and β¯c,t
                                                                  z
                                                                                                                                             β¯i,c,t
                                                                                                                                               z
                                                                        P
                                                                      =                                    P
                                                                                                              θi,c,t zˆi,t ( ψi,c,t −β¯i,c,t
                                                                                                                                       w             )
                                                                                                     i∈I   i∈I

is the weighted average sensitivity of industry×city employment growth to national growth. Ec,t (β a a
                                                                                                     ˆ) ≡
               ψ
                         β a (ω)ˆ
P                      R
    θi,c,t ψi,c,ti,c,t
                  −β¯w
                                a(ω)gi,c,t (ω)dω is the average growth due to asset accumulation.
                 i,c,t
i∈I                      Ω
                                                                                                                                     1
      Notice that the sensitivity of labor growth to idiosyncratic productivity growth β z =                                     1−ηl,k ηk,l (ηl,z +
                                                    z        f                            l                           f
ηl,k ηk,z ) depends positively on ηk,z = − fk,zk,z                                  k,l
                                                −ck k and negatively on ηk,l = − fk,l −ck k . Using the

first order condition that c(k ? , a) = fk (z, k ? , l? ) These can be written as:

                                                       ∂fk z                             ∂fk l
                                                       ∂z fk                              ∂l fk
                                         ηk,z =    ∂fk k     ∂c k
                                                                      , ηk,l =       ∂fk k      ∂c k
                                                   ∂k fk − ∂k c                      ∂k fk − ∂k c


                                                                                ∂c k
Thus a greater elasticity of marginal cost of capital with respect to capital ( ∂k c ), ie a steeper capital

supply curve, results in a lower sensitivity of labor growth with respect to productivity growth.20

      What this model shows is that labor growth can come from two sources. First, productivity

growth increases the optimal scale of production bringing about growth in employment, particularly

among firms with lower financial constraints (a flatter capital supply curve). Second, productivity

growth can come from a reduction in the cost of capital. For example if external finance is pro-

hibitively costly, firms will grow by accumulating profits. This form of growth reflects credit frictions

prohibiting firms from entering at an efficient scale.

      The concern is that asset growth and productivity growth are unobservable. Thus we need a
  19 Since the focus is on cyclical movements instead of a long term equilibrium, this seems more reasonable than

allowing frictionless movement across industries.
  20 There is also a general equilibrium effect of capital constraints on wages when there is an aggregate productivity

shock, as capital constraints make demand less elastic. But this is second order to the others


                                                                     118
proxy for productivity growth which is uncorrelated with asset growth to identify differences in β¯c,t

by county. Note that aggregate growth by industry is


                      ˆli,t =
                                X                                          ψi,c,t
                                      θ˜i,c,t ˆli,c,t = zˆi,t Ei,t (                    β¯i,c,t
                                                                                          z
                                                                                                ) + Ei,t (β a a
                                                                                                              ˆ)
                                c∈C
                                                                       ψi,c,t − β¯i,c,t
                                                                                  w



Where the expectation is the expected value over cities weighted by the density of i’s employment

in city c. Simply using national growth as a proxy for productivity shocks is problematic as trend

growth may be correlated with past profits and thus available assets. Also, correlation of asset

growth is problematic. For example, if productivity follows a jump process, unconstrained firms

may quickly reach their maximum scale, while constrained firms lag behind. However, after the

jump there may be high national growth as many firms want to increase their scale. But it will be

the constrained firms which have high growth, making the correlation related to frictions instead

of the lack thereof. Asset growth will depend on profits and thus the level of productivity instead

of its changes, making it a slow moving variable. Detrending the series should roughly remove the

employment growth attributable to trend productivity or asset accumulation. Thus the cyclical

component of employment growth should be:


                                           ˆlcyc ' zˆcyc Ei,t (        ψi,c,t
                                                                                    β¯i,c,t
                                                                                      z
                                                                                            )
                                             i,t     i,t
                                                                   ψi,c,t − β¯i,c,t
                                                                              w



Returning to the expression for county-industry growth,

                                                                                     Z
                 ˆli,c,t =       ψi,c,t                  cyc
                                              [β¯i,c,t
                                                 z
                                                       (ˆ
                                                        zi,t     trend
                                                             + zˆi,t   )+                β a (ω)ˆ
                                                                                                a(ω)gi,c,t (ω)dω]
                             ψi,c,t − β¯i,c,t
                                        w
                                                                                     Ω


                                            ψi,c,t
                                        ψi,c,t −β¯i,c,t
                                                  w     β¯i,c,t
                                                          z
                       ˆli,c,t =                               ˆlcyc        + i,c,t = β¯i,c,t
                                                                                         l     ˆlcyc + i,c,t
                                              ψi,c,t      ¯z     i,t                             i,t
                                   Ei,t ( ψi,c,t −β¯w βi,c,t )
                                                    i,c,t


Where  is the growth attributable to trend productivity and to asset growth. Thus the sensitivity

of local growth employment to national employment growth reflects how responsive a city×industry

is to a productivity shock relative to other the industry in the other cities. This sensitivity has been

shown to depend on the level of financial frictions in the city. Aggregating to the city level:

                                                X                              X
                                      ˆlc,t =         θi,c,t ˆli,c,t = β¯c,t
                                                                         l
                                                                                     θi,c,t ˆli,t + 
                                                i∈I                            i∈I




                                                                  119
                                                                                    θi,c,t ˆ
                                                                                           li,t ¯l
where θi,c,t denotes the share of employment in industry i, and β¯c,t
                                                                  l
                                                                        P
                                                                      =            P             β )
                                                                                             li,t i,c,t
                                                                                      θi,c,t ˆ
                                                                                                          is the
                                                                             i∈I   i∈I
weighted average sensitivity of industry×city employment growth to national growth. Suppose that

β¯i,c,t
  l
        = α1 − α2 HHIc,t , then we get the estimating equation used in the empirical section. α2 tells

us how much the bartik sensitivity declines when concentration goes up, thus informing us of the

degree to which firms are facing upward sloping supply curves.


3.7.5    Data Sources

Summary of Deposits         The Summary of Deposits (SOD) is an annual survey of all FDIC-insured

institutions. Each branch of commercial banks or savings and loans located within the US reports

the value of the deposits at that branch as of June 30. For institutions with more than one branch,

the assignment of deposits over the institution’s branches are instructed to be done in a “manner

consistent with their existing internal record keeping practices”, for example nearest branch to

account, most active branch of the account, place of origination, etc. I use the years 1994-2012. Also

included in the data are the address of the branch, the range of services available at the branch, and

identifiers for the financial institution and, if applicable, the holding company the branch is part of.


Call Reports Report of Condition and Income data (Call Reports) are available on a quarterly

basis for banks regulated by the Fed, FDIC, and the Comptroller of the Currency. I use data from

1994-2010, the first year SOD data is publicly available to the last year the Chicago Fed makes

the Call Report data. It provides information on the balance sheet, incomes and expenditures of

banks. Banks are linked to their locations in the SOD data using their RSSD ID. Stock variables

(e.g. loans ) are measured as the average of the first quarter and last quarter reported amounts,

while income and expenditure variables (e.g. loan income, interest paid on deposits) use the fourth

quarter reports giving the total received or paid during the calendar year.

   Variables often exhibit some extreme outliers, likely due to reporting errors or small denomina-

tors, so the highest and lowest 1% of values every year are dropped.


Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages                  The Quarterly Census of Employment and

Wages (QCEW) provides payroll and employment data at the MSA level for NAICS industries

using administrative records from state unemployment insurance programs. It covers roughly 97%

of the employment in the US. Employment is measured as filled jobs, so that people working multiple

jobs will be counted multiple times in the data. Each establishment is allocated to an NAICS code,

based on their primary activity.


                                                  120
   I only include people working in private industries, since public sector establishments aren’t

going to be subject to sensitive to credit market frictions, and won’t make hiring decisions with the

objective of profit maximization.


Business Dynamic Statistics The Business Dynamics Statistics (BDS) is developed by the

Center for Economic Studies using the the US Census Bureau’s Longitudinal Business Database, a

panel of US business establishments. Employment is full and part time employment as of march

12th. A firm is assigned an initial age of the age of the oldest establishment at time of birth. Firm

age then increase by 1 every year thereafter. A firm is considered young in year t if it’s age is five

or below and mature otherwise.




                                                 121
Bibliography

ABA (2006). Bank mergers and acquisitions handbook. ABA Web Store.

Adelino, M., A. Schoar, and F. Severino (2013). House prices, collateral and self-employment.

  Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Agarwal, S. and R. Hauswald (2010). Distance and private information in lending. Review of

  Financial Studies, hhq001.

Almeida, H., M. Campello, B. Laranjeira, and S. Weisbenner (2012, January). Corporate debt

  maturity and the real effects of the 2007 credit crisis. Critical Finance Review 1(1), 3–58.

Ashcraft, A. B. (2004). Are bank holding companies a source of strength to their banking sub-

  sidiaries? FRB of New York Staff Report (189).

Ashcraft, A. B. (2005). Are banks really special? new evidence from the fdic-induced failure of

  healthy banks. The American Economic Review 95(5), 1712.

Ashcraft, A. B. (2006). New evidence on the lending channel. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,

  751–775.

Barth, J. R., G. Caprio Jr, and R. Levine (2004). Bank regulation and supervision: what works

  best? Journal of Financial intermediation 13(2), 205–248.

Bartik, T. J. (1991). Who benefits from state and local economic development policies? Books from

  Upjohn Press.

Bassett, W. F., M. B. Chosak, J. C. Driscoll, and E. Zakrajˇsek (2014). Changes in bank lending

  standards and the macroeconomy. Journal of Monetary Economics 62, 23–40.

Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic (2004). Bank competition and access to finance:

  International evidence. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36(3), 627–648.

                                                122
Bellucci, A., A. Borisov, and A. Zazzaro (2013). Do banks price discriminate spatially? evidence from

  small business lending in local credit markets. Journal of Banking & Finance 37(11), 4183–4197.

Benmelech, E., N. K. Bergman, and A. Seru (2011). Financing labor. Technical report, National

  Bureau of Economic Research.

Berger, A. N. (1995).    The profit-structure relationship in banking–tests of market-power and

  efficient-structure hypotheses. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 404–431.

Berger, A. N. and T. H. Hannan (1989). The price-concentration relationship in banking. The

  Review of Economics and Statistics, 291–299.

Berger, A. N. and T. H. Hannan (1998). The efficiency cost of market power in the banking industry:

  A test of the quiet life and related hypotheses. Review of Economics and Statistics 80(3), 454–465.

Berger, A. N., N. H. Miller, M. A. Petersen, R. G. Rajan, and J. C. Stein (2005). Does function

  follow organizational form? evidence from the lending practices of large and small banks. Journal

  of Financial economics 76(2), 237–269.

Berger, A. N. and G. F. Udell (2002). Small business credit availability and relationship lending:

  The importance of bank organisational structure. The economic journal 112(477), F32–F53.

Bernanke, B. S., C. S. Lown, and B. M. Friedman (1991). The credit crunch. Brookings papers on

  economic activity 1991(2), 205–247.

Berrospide, J. M., L. Black, and W. R. Keeton (2013). The cross-market spillover of economic shocks

  through multi-market banks.

Black, S. E. and P. E. Strahan (2002). Entrepreneurship and bank credit availability. The Journal

  of Finance 57(6), 2807–2833.

Bord, V. M., V. Ivashina, and R. D. Taliaferro (2014). Large banks and the transmission of financial

  shocks.

Brevoort, K. P. and T. H. Hannan (2006). Commercial lending and distance: Evidence from com-

  munity reinvestment act data. Journal of Money, Credit & Banking (Ohio State University

  Press) 38(8).

Brevoort, K. P. and J. D. Wolken (2009). Does distance matter in banking? Springer.



                                                123
Buera, F. J. and Y. Shin (2013). Financial frictions and the persistence of history: A quantitative

  exploration. Journal of Political Economy 121(2), 221–272.

Campello, M., J. R. Graham, and C. R. Harvey (2010). The real effects of financial constraints:

  Evidence from a financial crisis. Journal of Financial Economics 97(3), 470–487.

Carb´
    o-Valverde, S., F. Rodriguez-Fernandez, and G. F. Udell (2009). Bank market power and sme

  financing constraints*. Review of Finance 13(2), 309–340.

Cetorelli, N. and M. Gambera (2001). Banking market structure, financial dependence and growth:

  International evidence from industry data. The Journal of Finance 56(2), 617–648.

Cetorelli, N. and L. S. Goldberg (2012). Banking globalization and monetary transmission. The

  Journal of Finance 67(5), 1811–1843.

Cetorelli, N. and P. E. Strahan (2006). Finance as a barrier to entry: Bank competition and industry

  structure in local us markets. The Journal of Finance 61(1), 437–461.

Chaney, T., D. Sraer, and D. Thesmar (2012). The collateral channel: How real estate shocks affect

  corporate investment. The American Economic Review 102(6), 2381–2409.

Chava, S. and A. Purnanandam (2011). The effect of banking crisis on bank-dependent borrowers.

  Journal of Financial Economics 99(1), 116–135.

Chodorow-Reich, G. (2014). The employment effects of credit market disruptions: Firm-level evi-

  dence from the 2008–9 financial crisis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(1), 1–59.

Chong, T. T.-L., L. Lu, and S. Ongena (2013). Does banking competition alleviate or worsen credit

  constraints faced by small-and medium-sized enterprises? evidence from china. Journal of Banking

  & Finance 37(9), 3412–3424.

Claessens, S. and L. Laeven (2005). Financial dependence, banking sector competition, and economic

  growth. Journal of the European Economic Association 3(1), 179–207.

Cole, R. A. and L. J. White (2012). D´ej`a vu all over again: The causes of us commercial bank

  failures this time around. Journal of Financial Services Research 42(1-2), 5–29.

Coleman, N. and L. Feler (2014). Bank ownership, lending, and local economic performance during

  the 2008–2009 financial crisis. Journal of Monetary Economics.



                                                124
Cornett, M. M., J. J. McNutt, P. E. Strahan, and H. Tehranian (2011). Liquidity risk management

  and credit supply in the financial crisis. Journal of Financial Economics 101(2), 297–312.

C´
 urdia, V. and M. Woodford (2010). Credit spreads and monetary policy. Journal of Money, Credit

  and Banking 42(s1), 3–35.

Daly, M., B. Hobijn, and B. Lucking (2012). Why has wage growth stayed strong? FRBSF Economic

  Letter 10(2).

Degryse, H. and S. Ongena (2005). Distance, lending relationships, and competition. The Journal

  of Finance 60(1), 231–266.

Driscoll, J. C. (2004). Does bank lending affect output? evidence from the us states. Journal of

  Monetary Economics 51(3), 451–471.

Duchin, R., O. Ozbas, and B. A. Sensoy (2010). Costly external finance, corporate investment, and

  the subprime mortgage credit crisis. Journal of Financial Economics 97(3), 418–435.

Duygan-Bump, B., A. Levkov, and J. Montoriol-Garriga (2015). Financing constraints and unem-

  ployment: evidence from the great recession. Journal of Monetary Economics.

Eggertsson, G. B. and P. Krugman (2012). Debt, deleveraging, and the liquidity trap: A fisher-

  minsky-koo approach*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, qjs023.

Elsby, M. W., D. Shin, and G. Solon (2013). Wage adjustment in the great recession. Technical

  report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Evanoff, D. D. and D. L. Fortier (1988).      Reevaluation of the structure-conduct-performance

  paradigm in banking. Journal of Financial Services Research 1(3), 277–294.

Fairlie, R. W. and H. A. Krashinsky (2012). Liquidity constraints, household wealth, and en-

  trepreneurship revisited. Review of Income and Wealth 58(2), 279–306.

Fischer, K.-H. (2000). Acquisition of information in loan markets and bank market power-an em-

  pirical investigation.

Fort, T. C., J. Haltiwanger, R. S. Jarmin, and J. Miranda (2013). How firms respond to business

  cycles: The role of firm age and firm size. IMF Economic Review 61(3), 520–559.

Friend, K., H. Glenos, and J. B. Nichols (2013). An analysis of the impact of the commercial real

  estate concentration guidance. Technical report.

                                               125
Gan, J. (2007). The real effects of asset market bubbles: Loan-and firm-level evidence of a lending

  channel. Review of Financial Studies 20(6), 1941–1973.

Gerali, A., S. Neri, L. Sessa, and F. M. Signoretti (2010). Credit and banking in a dsge model of

  the euro area. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42(s1), 107–141.

Gertler, M. and S. Gilchrist (1994). Monetary policy, business cycles, and the behavior of small

  manufacturing firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 309–340.

Goetz, M. R. and J. C. Gozzi (2010). Liquidity shocks, local banks, and economic activity: Evidence

  from the 2007-2009 crisis. SSRN Working Paper Series.

Greenstone, M., A. Mas, and H.-L. Nguyen (2014). Do credit market shocks affect the real economy?

  quasi-experimental evidence from the great recession and normaleconomic times. Technical report,

  National Bureau of Economic Research.

Gropp, R., J. Krainer, and E. Laderman (2014). Did consumers want less debt? consumer credit

  demand versus supply in the wake of the 2008-2009 financial crisis. Technical report.

Guerrieri, V. and G. Lorenzoni (2015). Credit crises, precautionary savings, and the liquidity trap.

Hadi, A. (2011). Construction employment peaks before the recession and falls sharply throughout

  it. Monthly Labor Review 134(4), 24–27.

Haltiwanger, J., R. S. Jarmin, and J. Miranda (2013). Who creates jobs? small versus large versus

  young. Review of Economics and Statistics 95(2), 347–361.

Hancock, D. and J. A. Wilcox (1994). Bank capital and the credit crunch: The roles of risk-weighted

  and unweighted capital regulations. Real Estate Economics 22(1), 59–94.

Hannan, T. H. (1991). Bank commercial loan markets and the role of market structure: Evidence

  from surveys of commercial lending. Journal of Banking & Finance 15(1), 133–149.

Hannan, T. H. and A. N. Berger (1991). The rigidity of prices: Evidence from the banking industry.

  The American Economic Review, 938–945.

Hannan, T. H. and J. N. Liang (1995). The influence of thrift competition on bank business loan

  rates. Journal of Financial Services Research 9(2), 107–122.

Heitfield, E. and R. A. Prager (2004). The geographic scope of retail deposit markets. Journal of

  Financial Services Research 25(1), 37–55.

                                                126
Heitfield, E. A. (1999). What do interest rate data say about the geography of retail banking

  markets? Antitrust Bull. 44, 333.

Hoffmann, F. and T. Lemieux (2014). Unemployment in the great recession: a comparison of

  germany, canada and the united states. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Houston, J., C. James, and D. Marcus (1997). Capital market frictions and the role of internal

  capital markets in banking. Journal of Financial Economics 46(2), 135–164.

Huang, H. and E. Stephens (2011). From housing bust to credit crunch: Evidence from small

  business loans. University of Alberta Department of Economics Working Paper 15.

Iacoviello, M. M. (2011). Housing wealth and consumption. FRB International Finance Discussion

  Paper (1027).

Ivashina, V. and D. Scharfstein (2010). Bank lending during the financial crisis of 2008. Journal of

  Financial economics 97(3), 319–338.

Jackson III, W. E. and R. A. Eisenbeis (1997). Geographic integration of bank deposit markets

  and restrictions on interstate banking: A cointegration approach. Journal of Economics and

  Business 49(4), 335–346.

Jayaratne, J. and P. E. Strahan (1996). The finance-growth nexus: Evidence from bank branch

  deregulation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 111(3), 639–670.

Jayaratne, J. and P. E. Strahan (1998). Entry restrictions, industry evolution, and dynamic effi-

  ciency: Evidence from commercial banking. JL & Econ. 41, 239.

Jim´enez, G., A. Mian, J.-L. Peydr´o, and J. Saurina (2014). The real effects of the bank lending

  channel.

Kahle, K. M. and R. M. Stulz (2013). Access to capital, investment, and the financial crisis. Journal

  of Financial Economics 110(2), 280–299.

Kashyap, A. K., R. Rajan, and J. C. Stein (2002). Banks as liquidity providers: An explanation for

  the coexistence of lending and deposit-taking. The Journal of Finance 57(1), 33–73.

Kerr, W. R. and R. Nanda (2010). Banking deregulations, financing constraints, and firm entry size.

  Journal of the European Economic Association 8(2-3), 582–593.



                                                127
Khwaja, A. I. and A. Mian (2008). Tracing the impact of bank liquidity shocks: Evidence from an

  emerging market. The American Economic Review, 1413–1442.

King, R. G. and R. Levine (1993). Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. The quarterly

  journal of economics 108(3), 717–737.

Kwast, M. L., M. Starr-McCluer, and J. D. Wolken (1997). Market definition and the analysis of

  antitrust in banking.

Levine, R. (2005). Finance and growth: theory and evidence. Handbook of economic growth 1,

  865–934.

Loutskina, E. and P. E. Strahan (2009). Securitization and the declining impact of bank finance on

  loan supply: Evidence from mortgage originations. Journal of Finance 64(2), 861–889.

Loutskina, E. and P. E. Strahan (2015). Financial integration, housing, and economic volatility.

  Journal of Financial Economics 115(1), 25–41.

Mehrotra, N. and D. Sergeyev (2014). Financial shocks and job flows.

Mian, A., K. Rao, and A. Sufi (2013). Household balance sheets, consumption, and the economic

  slump*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128(4), 1687–1726.

Mian, A. and A. Sufi (2014). What explains the 2007–2009 drop in employment? Econometrica 82(6),

  2197–2223.

Midrigan, V. and T. Philippon (2011). Household leverage and the recession.

Moll, B. (2014). Productivity losses from financial frictions: Can self-financing undo capital misal-

  location? The American Economic Review 104(10), 3186–3221.

Mondragon, J. (2014). Household credit and employment in the great recession. Available at SSRN

  2521177.

Morgan, D. P., B. Rime, and P. E. Strahan (2004). Bank integration and state business cycles. The

  Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(4), 1555–1584.

Myers, S. C. and N. S. Majluf (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms

  have information that investors do not have. Journal of financial economics 13(2), 187–221.

Neumark, D. and S. A. Sharpe (1992). Market structure and the nature of price rigidity: evidence

  from the market for consumer deposits. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 657–680.

                                                128
Peek, J. and E. Rosengren (1995). The capital crunch: neither a borrower nor a lender be. Journal

  of Money, Credit and Banking 27(3), 625–638.

Peek, J. and E. S. Rosengren (1994). Bank real estate lending and the new england capital crunch.

  Real Estate Economics 22(1), 33–58.

Peek, J. and E. S. Rosengren (1997). The international transmission of financial shocks: The case

  of japan. The American Economic Review 87(4), 495.

Peek, J. and E. S. Rosengren (2000). Collateral damage: Effects of the japanese bank crisis on real

  activity in the united states. American Economic Review, 30–45.

Peek, J., E. S. Rosengren, and G. Tootell (2003). Identifying the macroeconomic effect of loan supply

  shocks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 35(6), 931–46.

Petersen, M. A. and R. G. Rajan (1995). The effect of credit market competition on lending

  relationships. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(2), 407–443.

Petersen, M. A. and R. G. Rajan (2002). Does distance still matter? the information revolution in

  small business lending. The Journal of Finance 57(6), 2533–2570.

Pilloff, S. J. and S. A. Rhoades (2002). Structure and profitability in banking markets. Review of

  Industrial Organization 20(1), 81–98.

Radecki, L. J. (1998). The expanding geographic reach of retail banking markets. Economic Policy

  Review 4(2).

Rajan, R. and L. Zingales (1998). Financial dependence and growth. The American Economic

  Review 88(3), 559–586.

Rhoades, S. A. (1985). Market share as a source of market power: Implications and some evidence.

  Journal of Economics and Business 37(4), 343–363.

Rhoades, S. A. (1995). Market share inequality, the hhi, and other measures of the firm-composition

  of a market. Review of Industrial Organization 10(6), 657–674.

Rice, T. and E. Davis (2007). The branch banking boom in illinois: A byproduct of restrictive

  branching laws. Chicago Fed Letter (238).

Rice, T. and J. Rose (2014). When good investments go bad: The contraction in community bank

  lending after the 2008 gse takeover. Available at SSRN 2409328.

                                                129
Robb, A. M. and D. T. Robinson (2012). The capital structure decisions of new firms. Review of

  Financial Studies, hhs072.

Rognlie, M., A. Shleifer, and A. Simsek (2014). Investment hangover and the great recession.

  Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Saiz, A. (2010).   The geographic determinants of housing supply.        The Quarterly Journal of

  Economics 125(3), 1253–1296.

Santos, J. A. (2011). Bank corporate loan pricing following the subprime crisis. Review of Financial

  Studies 24(6), 1916–1943.

Sharpe, S. A. (1990). Asymmetric information, bank lending, and implicit contracts: A stylized

  model of customer relationships. The Journal of Finance 45(4), 1069–1087.

Slovin, M. B., M. E. Sushka, and J. A. Polonchek (1993). The value of bank durability: Borrowers

  as bank stakeholders. Journal of Finance, 247–266.

Smirlock, M. (1985). Evidence on the (non) relationship between concentration and profitability in

  banking. Journal of money, credit and Banking, 69–83.

Townsend, R. M. (1979). Optimal contracts and competitive markets with costly state verification.

  Journal of Economic theory 21(2), 265–293.

Weiss, L. W. (1989). A review of concentration-price studies in banking. Concentration and price 259.

Wurgler, J. (2000).     Financial markets and the allocation of capital.       Journal of financial

  economics 58(1), 187–214.

Zarutskie, R. (2003). Does bank competition affect how much firms can borrow? new evidence from

  the us. In Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Proceedings, Number 856.




                                                130